0
George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State
The University of Chicago Booth School of Business
Committee for the Study of Digital Platforms
Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee
Report
DRAFT
15 May 2019
1
Subcommittee members
Fiona Scott Morton (chair), Theodore Nierenberg Professor of Economics, Yale School of
Management
Pascal Bouvier, Managing Partner, MiddleGame Ventures
Ariel Ezrachi, Slaughter and May Professor of Competition Law, The University of Oxford
Bruno Jullien, Senior Researcher, CNRS, Toulouse School of Economics
Roberta Katz, Senior Research Scholar, Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences,
Stanford University
Gene Kimmelman, President and CEO of Public Knowledge
A. Douglas Melamed, Professor of the Practice of Law, Stanford Law School
Jamie Morgenstern, Assistant Professor of Computer Science, Georgia Institute of Technology
Acknowledgements
We thank Luigi Zingales and Guy Rolnik for inviting us to spend our time on this interesting and
complex project, and all the wonderful staff at the Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy
and the State. We particularly thank Rachel Piontek for her logistic and document skills, and
Filippo Lancieri for guiding the intellectual work along from the very start. Many thanks for
outstanding help with content go to students Doni Bloomfield, Rachel Cheong, and Steffi
Ostrowski of the Yale Law School. We are grateful to the reviewers at other institutions who
took time to give wise and helpful comments. We additionally want to thank our colleagues in
other nations whose reports came out before ours and provided stimulating ideas and
frameworks. We particularly build on the “Unlocking digital competition: Report of the Digital
Competition Expert Panel” chaired by Jason Furman for the Government of the United Kingdom
and the European Commission’s Special Advisors’ report “Competition Policy for the Digital
Era.
DISCLAIMER:
The purpose of these preliminary reports is to identify what are the new challenges digital
platforms pose to the economic and political structure of our countries. These reports also try to
identify the set of possible tools that might address these challenges. Yet, there is potential
disagreement among the members of the committees on which of these problems is most
troubling, which tools might work best, whether some tools will work at all or even whether the
damage they might produce is larger than the problem they are trying to fix. Not all committee
members agree with all the findings or proposals contained in this report. The purpose of
these preliminary reports, thus, is not to unanimously provide a perfect list of policy fixes but
to identify conceptual problems and solutions and start an academic discussion from
which robust policy recommendations can eventually be drafted.
2
Table of Contents
Introduction ....................................................................................................................................4
Executive Summary .......................................................................................................................6
IMPORTANT FEATURES OF THE DIGITAL BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT .................11
The Structure of Digital Markets ...............................................................................................11
An Economic Perspective on Digital Market Structure .........................................................11
Barriers to Entry and Expansion ............................................................................................17
How Big Data Affects Digital Products and the Sale of Advertisement....................................21
What Makes Data Big? And Does Big Data Harm Consumers? ..........................................21
Data Control and Ownership ..................................................................................................28
Digital Platforms are Characterized by Free Services ...........................................................32
PROBLEMS ARISING IN DIGITAL MARKETS .................................................................34
Quality Harms ...........................................................................................................................35
Personal Data and Behavioral Economics .............................................................................35
The Harms from an Advertising-Supported Business Model ...............................................38
Online Exploitation and Addiction ........................................................................................41
The Assessment Problem ..........................................................................................................45
Measuring Consumer Welfare in a Behavioral World ..........................................................45
Assessing the Social Welfare of Advertising .........................................................................46
Harms to Investment and Innovation ........................................................................................46
Rents .......................................................................................................................................46
Harm to Entry, Including Discrimination .................................................................................49
The Practical Consequences of Entry Barriers .......................................................................49
Incumbent Incentive to Leverage Entry Barriers ...................................................................49
Disintermediation and Foreclosure of Potential Platform Entrants ........................................50
Foreclosure of Complements to Capture Rents .....................................................................51
Harm to Innovation ...................................................................................................................53
Competition Promotes Innovation .........................................................................................53
Entry Barriers and Innovation ...............................................................................................53
The Reward of Innovation .....................................................................................................55
3
Current Trends in Innovation ................................................................................................55
Old Wine in a New Bottle, or a New Reality? ..........................................................................57
SOLUTIONS ...............................................................................................................................59
Will Markets Self-Correct When Competition Problems Arise? ..............................................59
US Antitrust ...............................................................................................................................60
Basic Principles .....................................................................................................................60
Special Challenges Presented by Technology Platforms ..........................................................66
Could a Reformed Antitrust Law be Effective in Dealing with Digital Platforms? .................71
Reform by What Means? .......................................................................................................71
Reform of Antitrust Law Through General Tightening ........................................................73
Specific Areas of Possible Antitrust Reform .........................................................................74
A Competition Court .............................................................................................................78
A Regulatory Partner Could Enhance Effective Antitrust Enforcement ................................78
Regulation .................................................................................................................................79
The Digital Authority ............................................................................................................83
Menu of Regulations .............................................................................................................85
DA-Enforced Remedies for Antitrust Violations ..................................................................95
Aligning other Policies with Competition .............................................................................97
Adjudication Process .............................................................................................................97
CONCLUSION ...........................................................................................................................98
Boxes
Box I: Platforms vs. Brick-and-Mortar Advertising and Targeting ..........................................22
Box II: Why Data Has Increasing Marginal Returns ................................................................27
Box III: Digital Identities ..........................................................................................................31
Box IV: More About US Antitrust Law ....................................................................................61
Box V: EU Competition Law ....................................................................................................65
Box VI: The FCC Model ...........................................................................................................81
Box VII: Real Time Regulation in Financial Services ..............................................................86
4
I. Introduction
When the global, interactive, many-to-many communications network called the internet became
available for broad public use in 1995, people were overjoyed with the new power at their
fingertips. It is easy to forget that in the early years of the internet, that power was limited to
visiting shops and getting news from the relatively small number of enterprises that had built
websites on the World Wide Web. Over the past 25 years, that power has exploded with head-
spinning velocity: Today, there is no area of human life that has not been affected by the
technological innovations made possible by the internet. We now buy goods and services, do
banking, pay bills, find information, and talk with multiple groups of friends and acquaintances
on the web. The speed, scale, and scope of the internet, and of the ever-more powerful
technologies it has spawned, have been of unprecedented value to human society.
History teaches us that social institutions must adapt after major technological advances. In just
the past century, we saw this after the introduction of the automobile, the airplane, radio and
television, and cell phones, to name but a few examples. New occupations—for example, bus
driversarise to replace others—for example, buggy whip producers. At the same time, new
behavioral norms and expectations replace those associated with past technologies—consider the
social and economic changes wrought by the automobile, or the changes in both the rules and
norms of the workplace in the age of mobile devices. As unintended and unforeseen social
problems and harms arose, society responded with governance mechanisms aimed at addressing
the problems or harms without impeding the clear benefits associated with the advances. These
have ranged from the adoption of new social norms to the creation of new laws and regulations.
Examples abound, encompassing everything from crosswalks and traffic lights to legal remedies
addressing unfair competition in the marketplace. Ideally, the goal is to steer technological
advances to ensure widespread benefit without attendant widespread harms—to protect and
preserve innovation and advancement while minimizing harms so that all of society reaps net
benefits. Such a goal often involves government intervention and always involves tradeoffs as
society wrestles with the prevalence and cost of harms and how to balance them against the
prevalence and size of benefits. While often messy, this is a healthy and desirable debate.
This working group came together to address specific problems arising from the digital
platforms’ reach, scale, scope, and use of data. We were asked to examine concerns stemming
from the market structure contemporary platforms have created, and to investigate their
competitive behavior, including the consequences of network effects that can create barriers to
entry for new innovators and entrench incumbents. The global nature of many of today’s
platforms, a result of their scale, scope, and business models, creates novel complexities and
considerations, particularly a concern that the digital platform may be a unique combination of
economic forces that require both new analysis and new public policy. Regulatory authorities
throughout the world are now turning their attention to these same questions. This report
5
contributes to this international analytical project by providing some of the necessary
frameworks and inputs. We intend it to be a complement to other recent work, as experts across
the world wrestle with how to ensure that markets remain open and healthy, allowing beneficial
technological and social advancements to continue. Many of our conclusions and suggestions
echo the findings of reports that have come out in the past year, and we hope they will be helpful
to those reports not yet released. The list of antitrust experts and agencies working on this
problem includes Australia, the United Kingdom, Germany, the European Commission, France,
Israel, and Japan.
1
The issues are global in their scope, and these various jurisdictions are all engaged in analyzing
how best to ensure that societies in general, and competition in particular, continue to thrive in
the Digital Age. Our charge was restricted to market structure and competition, while other
committees considered the equally important topics of the impact of digital platforms on politics,
the media, and the nature of privacy. We note that monopolies can concentrate political power,
reduce media plurality, and provide insufficient competition on dimensions such as privacy. In
this way the findings of this report and the others are linked and quite consistent. Digital markets
and platforms have already delivered great benefits to consumers, and the global concerns that
have surfaced relating to actual or potential consumer harms may require action to ensure that
the benefits are not undermined. Our report concludes that with deliberate government action to
protect competition and consumers, the benefits from innovative firms could be even greater and
more equitably spread, ensuring that the public is not short-changed in firms’ pursuit of profit.
Accordingly, this report is offered in the spirit of ensuring a future of continued technological
and economic progress and social well-being as we move further forward into the Digital Age.
1
See JACQUES CREMER, YVES-ALEXANDRE DE MONTJOYE, & HEIKE SCHWEITZER, EURO. COMMN, DIRECTORATE-
G
ENERAL FOR COMPETITION, COMPETITION POLICY FOR THE DIGITAL ERA (Apr. 4, 2019),
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/publications/reports/kd0419345enn.pdf [hereinafter EC
COMPETITION REPORT];
J
ASON FURMAN ET AL., H.M. TREASURY (U.K.), UNLOCKING DIGITAL COMPETITION: REPORT OF THE DIGITAL
COMPETITION EXPERT PANEL (March 13, 2019),
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/785547/unlocking
_digital_competition_furman_review_web.pdf [hereinafter U.K.
COMPETITION REPORT]; AUSTL. COMPETITION &
CONSUMER COMMN, DIGITAL PLATFORMS INQUIRY: PRELIMINARY REPORT (Dec. 2018),
https://www.accc.gov.au/system/files/ACCC%20Digital%20Platforms%20Inquiry%20-
%20Preliminary%20Report.pdf [hereinafter A
USTRALIA COMPETITION REPORT]; Japanese Ministry of Economy,
Trade, & Industry, Fundamental Principles for Rule Making to Address the Rise of Platform Businesses Formulated,
(Dec. 18, 2018), https://www.meti.go.jp/english/press/2018/1218_002.html; H
EIKE SCHWEITZER ET AL., GERMAN
BUNDESMINISTERIUM WIRSCHAFT UND ENERGIE, MODERNISING THE LAW ON ABUSE OF MARKET POWER: REPORT
FOR THE
FEDERAL MINISTRY FOR ECONOMIC AFFAIRS AND ENERGY (Apr. 9, 2018),
https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/DE/Downloads/Studien/modernisierung-der-missbrauchsaufsicht-fuer-
marktmaechtige-unternehmen-zusammenfassung-englisch.pdf [hereinafter G
ERMAN COMPETITION REPORT
SUMMARY]; L’AUTORITÉ DE LA CONCURRENCE [FRENCH COMPETITION AUTHORITY], PORTANT SUR
L
EXPLOITATION DES DONNÉES DANS LE SECTEUR DE LA PUBLICITÉ SUR INTERNET [ON THE EXPLOITATION OF DATA
IN THE
INTERNET ADVERTISING SECTOR] (Mar. 6, 2018), http://www.autoritedelaconcurrence.fr/pdf/avis/18a03.pdf
[hereinafter F
RENCH COMPETITION REPORT]; Press Release, The Israel Antitrust Authority invites interested
members of the public to submit their comments, towards an inquiry into competition issues in the digital economy,
Reishut HaTachrut [Israel Antitrust Authority] (Apr. 9, 2018),
http://www.antitrust.gov.il/eng/subject/177/item/35246.aspx.
6
Executive Summary
a. Attributes
The market structure and antitrust report begins by discussing the characteristics of digital
markets. These markets often have extremely strong economies of scale and scope due to low
marginal costs and the returns to data. Moreover, they often are two-sided and have strong
network externalities and are therefore prone to tipping. If so, the competitive process shifts from
competition in the market to competition for the market. This combination of features means
many digital markets feature large barriers to entry. The winner in these settings often has a large
cost advantage from its scale of operations and a large benefit advantage from the scale of its
data. An entrant cannot generally overcome these without either a similar installed base (network
effects) or a similar scale (scale economies), both of which are difficult to obtain quickly and
cost-effectively.
Additional barriers to entry are, ironically, generated by the very consumers who are harmed by
them. Consumers do not scroll down to see more search results, they agree to settings chosen by
the service, they single-home on one platform, and they generally take actions that favor the
status quo and make it difficult for an entrant to attract consumers. In general, the findings from
the behavioral economics literature demonstrate an under-recognized market power held by
incumbent digital platforms.
The theme that runs throughout the report is the difficulty of entry into digital platform
businesses once an incumbent is established. Whether the entrant is vertical or horizontal, has
succeeded to some degree, is nascent, is a potential entrant, or is a large platform in an adjacent
space, its existence improves consumer welfare. Either the entrant provides more choice,
different features, and a chance of higher quality, or the threat of those outcomes spurs the
incumbent to provide lower prices, higher quality and innovation, and to do so more quickly.
The role of data in digital sectors is critical. Personal data of all types allows for targeted
advertising to consumers, a common revenue model for platforms. The report shows that the
returns to more dimensions and types of data may be increasing, which again advantages
incumbents. Consumer data in the United States is not regulated in any way that gives useful
control or privacy to consumers; and additionally, most consumers have little idea what is being
collected about them and re-sold. One way in which digital platforms often exploit their market
power – and increase their profits – is by requiring consumers to agree to terms and conditions
that are unclear, difficult to understand, and constantly changing, but which give the platform
freedom to monetize consumers’ personal data.
Digital platforms are characterized by free services. “Free” is not a special zone where
economics or antitrust do not apply. Rather, a free good is one where the seller has chosen to set
7
a monetary price of zero and may set other, non-monetary, conditions or duties. It is possible that
a digital market has an equilibrium price that is negative; in other words, because of the value of
target advertising, the consumer’s data is so valuable that the platform would pay for it. But the
difficulty of making micropayments might lead a platform to mark up this negative competitive
price to zero. As a result, barter is a common way in which consumers pay for digital services.
They barter their privacy and information about what restaurants they would like to eat in and
what goods they would like to buy in exchange for digital services. However, in principle, that
information has a market price that can be analyzed.
b. Harms
Market power, consumer biases and an ad-supported platform model can generate significant
consumer harms. First, market power in advertising markets will result in markups paid by
advertisers. Secondly, while behavioral economists have studied consumer biases and firm
responses in offline markets, these are swamped by what digital businesses can learn by using
high-dimensional, large datasets to explore every nook and cranny of consumers’ many
behavioral shortcomings and biases in real time. Framing, nudges, and defaults can direct a
consumer to the choice that is most profitable for the platform. A platform can analyze a user’s
data in real time to determine when she is in an emotional “hot state” and then offer targeted
sales. These tactics reduce the quality of the zero-price content the user experiences on the
platform.
In addition to de novo entry, platforms fear disintermediation by a partner or complement. If a
platform’s partner is able to directly access and serve the platform’s customers, it might take
them off the platform entirely, reducing the platform’s profit. A platform that has total control of
demand due to control over framing of consumer choices, policies for complements, and
technical standards can steer customers to content and complements of most benefit to it. The
most privately beneficial content might be owned by the platform itself rather than provided by
independent firms that could extract rent or even challenge the platform’s market power in the
future. To the extent that consumers single-home, they may not be aware of such steering, or
may not have competitive alternatives to which they can turn if they are aware.
Today’s platforms understand that in some settings they can obtain higher margins if they either,
make all of the necessary complements themselves, or, position themselves as a mandatory
bottleneck between partners and customers. In particular, digital platforms are often very careful
to maintain complete control over the user relationship so that they do not face any threat of
disintermediation from a complement. These technological and policy choices can be used to
reduce the possibility of successful entry by direct competitor. Other strategies such as exclusive
contracts, bundling, or technical incompatibilities can also be used by platforms to restrict entry
of competitors. Some of these strategies could be violations of existing antitrust law, as discussed
below.
8
Insufficient competition and entry result in harms to investment and innovation. There is
significant theoretical and empirical research that concludes that anticompetitive creation or
maintenance of market power will cause a reduction in the pace of innovation.
.
The lessening or
blocking of innovative entry is of particular concern given its value to consumers. A VC will
usually be wary of outright investing in an innovative startup that will implicitly or explicitly
compete head-on with a tech giant. In that case, the best hope might be to be the preferred
innovator of a complement and sell its business to the platform at an early stage. However, if
entry barriers were reduced, the entrepreneur would not have to settle for a small fraction of the
platform’s profits, but could compete for all of them and try to replace the platform. This
possibility would generate a much larger incentive to innovate.
c. Solutions
While some markets may self-correct, the findings of this report suggest that rapid self-
correction in markets dominated by large digital platforms is unlikely.
While US antitrust law has long been flexible in combatting anticompetitive conduct, there is
increasing concern that it has been underenforced in recent years. Antitrust law and its
application by the courts over the past several decades have reflected the now outdated learning
of an earlier era of economic thought, and they appear in some respects inhospitable to new
learning. Antitrust enforcement better suited to the challenges of the Digital Age may therefore
require new legislation.
Technology platforms present particular challenges for antitrust enforcement. Markets tip and the
resulting market power is durable, so even effective antitrust enforcement is unlikely to generate
fragmented markets. Nonetheless, enforcement that protects competition on the merits in the first
stage and prevents exclusionary conduct in the second stage will help ensure that market-
participants make unfettered choices among competing platforms and that entry and innovation
are not inhibited by private rent-seeking.
Economists and lawyers will have to develop tools to explain to courts the role of behavioral
biases in the creation of market power and in their effect on the quality of content. The existence
of zero money prices means that measurement of quality will be critical. The law needs better
analytical tools to take into account the impact of potential and nascent competitors and
competition. Market definition will vary according to what consumers are substituting between,
whether there is competition on the platform between complements, or competition between
platforms, or competition between a platform and potential or nascent competitors regarding
possible future markets. The need to identify the specific anticompetitive exclusionary conduct
and analyze it may raise enforcement costs given all the possible variants of exclusionary
conduct possible in digital markets.
9
This report details the particular areas where antitrust law will need reform in order to adequately
deliver competition to consumers. The report also suggests the establishment of a specialist
competition court to hear all private and public antitrust cases which would allow judges to
develop some expertise. The committee believes that vigorously enforcing the antitrust laws
under these conditions would be likely to increase entry in digital platform industries,
competition, and consumer welfare. Moreover, such enforcement would likely result in remedies
to restore competition that has already been lost, as well as serve as a deterrent to future
anticompetitive conduct.
However, because technology platforms present the enforcement challenges detailed above, even
effective enforcement may not be enough to generate competitive digital markets in a timely
fashion. Therefore, the report suggests that Congress should consider creating a specialist
regulator, the Digital Authority. The regulator could be tasked with creating general conditions
conducive to competition. The committee also suggests separating out some types of regulation
that will apply to virtually all market participants while other regulation will apply only to
companies with bottleneck power. “Bottleneck power” describes a situation where consumers
primarily single-home and rely upon a single service provider, which makes obtaining access to
those consumers for the relevant activity by other service providers prohibitively costly.
The Digital Authority could routinely collect data on digital transactions and interactions, with
an emphasis on data from businesses with bottleneck power. These data – made public to the
extent possible – would allow policy makers and researchers to assess the performance of the
sector. The DA could have a mandate to create “light touch” behavioral nudges when they will
make markets more competitive. An example of a regulation that would enhance competition is
data portability. The DA could set up rules that allow users to easily port their data from one
service provider to another and monitor compliance. The DA may also promote open standards
in such areas as micro-payments and digital identities. Should Congress request it, the DA could
oversee a mandate for interoperability in any market where market power has become
entrenched and threatens long term harm to competition. The Report also suggests that the DA
could carry out a parallel merger review that would be set up to incorporate necessary antitrust
reforms and modern standards.
Some regulations could apply only to firms that meet the DA’s definition for bottleneck power.
Because the cost of false negatives is high and there is uncertainty, the public interest requires
the DA to take a more interventionist approach in these settings. The DA could have merger
review authority over even the smallest transactions involving digital businesses with bottleneck
power because nascent competition against these entities is very valuable for consumers. Non-
discrimination rules could protect against a complement that is a potential competitor of the
platform itself, or one that operates only on the platform as a rival provider of content.
10
When a company has been found liable for violating the antitrust laws, part of the current
process is that antitrust authority devises a remedy to restore the lost competition. Data sharing,
full protocol interoperability, non-discrimination requirements, and the unbundling of content
from a platform are all tools that the regulator, in conjunction with the antitrust authority, could
apply and monitor over time in order to restore competitive markets.
11
II. IMPORTANT FEATURES OF THE DIGITAL BUSINESS
ENVIRONMENT
Digital technologies are a central driver of future prosperity, hopefully delivering waves of
innovation, efficiencies, and consumer welfare. These technologies have revolutionized the way
consumers shop and communicate, the way businesses deliver value, the way people work
together in collaboration, and—the subject of this report—the overall dynamics of competition.
These transformative changes, while immensely beneficial, have also triggered growing concerns
about the power of a small number of firms to control and influence billions of lives. As an
increasing volume and range of commercial activities have been digitalized, society has
witnessed the emergence of certain key platforms and gatekeepers and a shift in market
dynamics.
This section outlines the key features of the digital environment to set the foundation for the
discussion of problems and solutions.
a. The Structure of Digital Markets
i. An Economic Perspective on the Digital Market Structure
Despite the predictions of some early observers that the internet would create competitiveeven
perfectmarkets,
2
certain digital firms have been able to acquire significant market positions
and preserve them over time. Many of the most innovative internet-derived digital markets, such
as search engines, social networks, network operating systems, ecommerce, and ride-sharing, are
highly concentrated and have been dominated by one or a few firms for a number of years. The
lack of entry of competitors in these important markets—despite high profits—suggests either
barriers to entry or exclusionary conduct, or both. We first discuss the nature of entry barriers in
digital platforms and why they are difficult for an entrant to surmount.
1) A Unique Setting Subject to Tipping
From an economic perspective, there is no single new characteristic that would make
competition in digital platforms different from more traditional markets. Rather, it is the
coincidence of several factors at a scale that has not been encountered before that makes the
problem unique and requires new analysis of market structure and market power. In particular,
2
See, e.g., Erik Brynjolfsson & Michael D. Smith, Frictionless Commerce? A Comparison of Internet and
Conventional Retailers, 46 M
GMT. SCI. 563, 563 (2000) (“The conventional wisdom regarding Internet competition .
. . is that the unique characteristics of the Internet will bring about a nearly perfect market.”); Jeffrey R. Brown &
Austan Goolsbee, Does the Internet Make Markets More Competitive? Evidence from the Life Insurance Industry,
110 J.
POL. ECON. 481, 482 (2002) (“The traditional economic view suggests that . . . the Internet should reduce
search costs for consumers and thereby reduce prices and make markets more competitive.”).
12
the platforms with which this report is most concerned demonstrate extremely strong network
effects, very strong economies of scale, remarkable economies of scope due to the role of data,
marginal costs close to zero, drastically lower distribution costs than brick and mortar firms, and
a global reach.
Markets with these combined features are prone to tipping—a cycle leading to a dominant firm
and high concentration. Digital markets are prone to tipping for two primary reasons. First,
because fixed costs play such an important role in digital markets, these markets feature
especially large returns to scale. Second, many digital markets are driven by network effects that
strengthen large incumbents and weaken new entrants.
When markets are prone to tipping, the competitive process shifts from competition in the
market to competition for the market. In that case, consumers may only benefit from competition
among several firms for the relatively short time period in which the firms compete to be the
ultimate winner of very large economic profits. The winner’s monopoly profits serve as the
inducement for entry and investment. After a market has tipped, a potential rival for the market
can only overcome the incumbency advantage of established networks through significant
innovation. However, even an innovative entrant may not be able to create competition that
benefits consumers in the presence of the factors that led to the tipping, leaving open a role for
public policy to allow for competition for the market. Moreover, a competitor is even less likely
to enter the market if the incumbent platform is able to leverage its powerful position to
disadvantage or exclude potential entrants.
There are many well-known problems that follow from lack of competition, including higher
prices, less innovation, and lower quality in all its forms. Policy may be needed to address the
cause of such symptomatic problems. In the view of this committee, protecting entry for existing
and potential competitors is the most important way to protect or improve consumer welfare in
digital platforms. Initial competition for a market should be conducted on the merits without any
anticompetitive practices, and later entrants should face a level playing field and no exclusionary
conduct as they contest the market. Regulation may be required to prevent incumbents from
erecting improper barriers to entry.
As it is traditionally recognized, the reward for the winner’s innovative activity is the ability to
extract rent from the platform through the exercise of market power.
3
However, we highlight
three deviations from this principle. First, the winner must have “won” on the merits of its
product, without the use of any anticompetitive conduct. Correcting illegal practices by dominant
firms that have won in a tipped digital market can be difficult, but is necessary or the firm will
earn profits from its illegal behavior—and harm consumers along the way. Second, the reward of
the entire market that propelled the winner to innovate must be available to the next entrant. If
3
See United States v. Alcoa, 148 F.2d 416, 430 (2d Cir. 1945) (“The successful competitor, having been urged to
compete, must not be turned upon when he wins.”) (Hand, J.).
13
the incumbent is able to withhold those rents by excluding the entrant, or reduce those rents by
limiting the entrant’s share, then the pace of innovation will slow. The economic literature
demonstrates that vibrant innovation and entry is the most important source of consumer welfare
over time—hence the focus of the report on ensuring that entry functions well both when a
market is created and thereafter.
4
Third, there are sources of platform rents that society may
determine through appropriate regulation should not be part of the winner’s reward. For
example, investments in complements offered on the platform may be best incentivized and
encouraged to compete if the platform owner is not entitled to exclude them. (As used in this
report, a complement is a good or service offered on or through the platform that increases the
value of the platform to a consumer.) Digital markets at issue today may not have featured free
entry and lack of anticompetitive conduct in the past. This report covers that case by describing
how antitrust can be used to look backward, as well as forward, for antitrust violations. We also
suggest regulation that can look forward to protect entrants, and thereby consumers, in these
other cases.
2) Increasing Returns to Scale
Digital markets are used to exchange information goods and services. Typically, information
goods involve increasing returns to scale because their production requires a fixed cost and no or
little variable cost.
5
In other words, when an additional user is served, costs do not go up
proportionately. For example, an eBook, once produced, can be distributed at almost no cost to
all users with access to the internet. The same holds for information services that are subject to
fixed design and development costs and fixed maintenance and updating costs; Google can
update Google Calendar for 100 million users with similar fixed expenses as would be needed
for only a fraction of such users.
In contrast to traditional media or cultural markets that have had to incur physical distribution
costs, digital markets are largely able to avoid such costs. The fact that information services can
be delivered to any geographic location with no or minimal cost is one reason for the abundance
of such services. The capacity to reach a large scale at small cost changes the nature of business
growth. While a traditional business often starts with local implementation followed by gradual
expansion through investment as reputation and financial resources increase, many online
businesses aim at rapid large-scale expansion. This rapid growth may reduce the length of the
competition-for-the-market phase, as market winners can establish dominance and begin
exercising their market power quickly. It took only five years for Facebook, the “move fast and
4
See, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Paul Klemperer, Coordination and Lock-In: Competition with Switching Costs and
Network Effects, in 3 H
ANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION (Mark Armstrong & Robert Porter eds., 2007),
https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1573448X06030317; Wen Wen & Feng Zhu, Threat of Platform-
Owner Entry and Complementor Responses: Evidence from the Mobile App Market, (Harvard Business School
Working Paper 18-036, 2018), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=284853.
5
Increasing returns to scale occur when the average unit cost decreases when sales expand.
14
break things” company, to go from a million users in 2004, the year of its founding, to more than
350 million users in 2009, when it overtook MySpace for good.
6
The implications for market structure are well known: increasing returns to scale lead companies
to invest in fixed costs in order to have the best product to attract customers.
7
Then, with a larger
customer base, the firm can enjoy lower average costs per consumer, allowing it to make an offer
to consumers that is attractive in both quality and price. The increasing returns to scale create
barriers to entry: New firms cannot offer the quality of the incumbent without the same large-
scale operation to pay for the fixed costs. But the firm can only achieve a large scale if quality is
high. Thus, a potential entrant, foreseeing that it will not be profitable at the smaller scale, will
not enter the market to challenge the incumbent.
3) Economies of Scope
Platforms also have powerful economies of scope in the form of their relationships with users
and brands. In digital markets specifically, scale offers an additional advantage. Firms can apply
machine learning to extensive data sets to improve their products and expand their activities into
new areas. Because machine learning yields better insights when it is trained on larger datasets,
firms with access to large amounts of data can raise the quality of their services in ways that
smaller firms cannot. This creates a form of dynamic economies of scale, allowing large firms
with large amounts of data to raise product quality at lower costs than small firms. Firms may
also be able to leverage the data, or the insights due to machine learning, that they receive from
an existing service to enter into an adjacent market with a higher quality product, demonstrating
a novel form of economies of scope. Combining mapping software in a platform that already
offers email, for example, allows that platform to offer a higher quality restaurant
recommendation product. Moreover, firms serving a larger customer base with a greater variety
of products are able to generate more advertising revenue per consumer through more effective
targeting.
8
The development of machine learning technologies and data analysis is a source of
increasing returns to scale and scope that can contribute to digital market concentration.
6
See Chloe Albanesius, More Americans Go to Facebook Than MySpace, PC MAG. (June 16, 2009),
https://www.pcmag.com/news/241432/more-americans-go-to-facebook-than-myspace; Ami Sedghi, Facebook: 10
Years of Social Netoworking, in Numbers, G
UARDIAN (Feb. 4, 2014),
https://www.theguardian.com/news/datablog/2014/feb/04/facebook-in-numbers-statistics. See also Steven Levy,
Mark Zuckerberg on Facebook's Future, From Virtual Reality to Anonymity, W
IRED (Apr. 30, 2014),
https://www.wired.com/2014/04/zuckerberg-f8-interview (reporting Mark Zuckerberg noting that “[w]e’ve changed
our internal motto from ‘Move fast and break things’ to ‘Move fast with stable infrastructure’”).
7
See generally JOHN SUTTON, SUNK COSTS AND MARKET STRUCTURE (1991).
8
Such economies of scope are leading to a rapid expansion of the capture and use of personal information by firms.
For example, many large firms are starting to expand beyond internet platforms in order to collect more data from
consumers. The rise of voice-assistant products (including Microsoft’s Cortana, Apple’s Siri, Google’s Google
Voice, and Amazon’s Alexa) can enable firms to gather information from offline consumer behavior and then feed
that information into online advertisement-targeting algorithms. One study estimates that major internet platforms,
data brokers, credit card companies, and healthcare data companies derived nearly $76 billion in 2018 from selling
personal consumer information directly or indirectly via targeted ads. Robert Shapiro & Siddhartha Aneja, Who
15
4) Network Effects
Most information services involve some form of positive network effects, in which consumer
benefit grows as the number of users increases. The simplest network effects flow directly from
interacting with other users, as in social networks or peer-to-peer services, such as eBay or
Venmo, where the more users there are on the network, the richer the users’ experience is likely
to be. (In these examples the platforms choose not to be interoperable, so the network effects
apply to a single firm, rather than an industry.) Multi-homing lessens network effects because a
consumer can enjoy the size of both networks, rather than having to choose one. For example, a
consumer that carries both Visa and American Express credit cards can shop at stores that accept
either card, or both. Many other network effects are indirect, in that they are mediated by a
“complement” to the network. A complement is a good or service that increases the value of
another good or service to a consumer. For example, the ability to not only make calls, but also
to play music on a handset increases the value of the handset to users. Complements today often
come in the form of applications (“apps”) or a specific type of content. The more complements a
platform has, the more popular it is with users. Just as customers of a popular app store receive
an indirect network effect when more and better developers are attracted to app stores with big
customer bases, customers of a widely-used social media site benefit from the many games
designed for that social media site, which in turn are driven by the large number of consumers.
These network effects can also be seen in recommendation systems or driving directions that
exploit larger datasets of users’ purchasing behavior or travel paths to offer higher quality
advice.
Markets with network effects are prone to concentration because consumers benefit from being
on the same network as other users. No one wants to be on their own social media site. However,
when network effects are exhausted relatively quickly (as can occur, for example, in messaging
apps
9
) or when there is heterogeneity in preferences (e.g. teenagers prefer not to be on the same
social network as their parents
10
), the market structure may be oligopolistic.
Owns Americans’ Personal Information and What Is It Worth?, FUTURE MAJORITY (Mar. 8, 2019),
https://assets.futuremajority.org/uploads/report-for-future-majority-on-the-value-of-people-s-personal-data-shapiro-
aneja-march-8-2019.pdf.
9
To send a message to someone, a user only needs that single person to be on a particular messaging app, rather
than everyone they would want to send a message to. This explains why many messaging apps can live alongside
one anotherWhatsApp, Snapchat, SMS, and Facebook Messenger all have significant customer bases. See Most
Popular Mobile Messaging Apps Worldwide as of January 2019, S
TATISTA (Jan. 2019),
https://www.statista.com/statistics/258749/most-popular-global-mobile-messenger-apps.
10
See Mark Sweney, Is Facebook for Old People? Over-55s Flock in as the Young Leave, GUARDIAN (Feb. 12,
2018), https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2018/feb/12/is-facebook-for-old-people-over-55s-flock-in-as-the-
young-leave.
16
Some indirect network effects are multi-sided: A user of one type (e.g., a buyer) benefits from
the participation of other types of users (e.g., sellers). For instance, in ecommerce platforms,
which intermediate trade between sellers and buyers, a buyer does not directly benefit from the
presence of other buyers but does benefit from the presence of more sellers—who are in turn
attracted by the presence of the buyers. Multi-sided network externalities are prominent on the
internet for two reasons. First, business models like ecommerce are plentiful. Second, and more
importantly, a great deal of activity on the internet is financed by paid advertising on the relevant
site. Advertising-financed services are platforms exploiting two-sided network effects between
advertisers and consumers. Advertising can be more valuable when there are more consumers
viewing a site, while consumers are attracted by content that may be of higher quality when
financed by many advertisers competing for space.
On multi-sided platforms, one or more sides may be subsidized if their participation attracts
paying customers on the other side. Thus, we may see a monetary price of zero in one part of a
very lucrative business model. Shoppers on eBay can buy without paying fees because eBay
understands that fees would drive them away, whereas their presence draws in sellers who can be
charged fees. Users of Gmail pay a monetary price of zero but allow Google to read their email
so that advertisers can market to them based on personal information. Google can then charge a
high price for the ads. Payment platforms such as credit cards or PayPal similarly charge end
consumers low or negative fees because a large group of consumers bring in retailers who pay
the payment platform for access.
Network effects can lead to consumer-friendly competition at early stages. Economic theory and
market observation indicate that during the phase when competitors are all trying to tip the
market towards themselves, they compete intensely. This phase is characterized by vigorous
competition between firms trying to build market shares and generate bandwagon effects. For
example, Uber and Lyft have hotly contested the market for ride-sharing—and spent billions of
dollars subsidizing riders’ fares along the way.
11
One 2016 estimate suggested that payments
from Uber customers covered only about 40% of the cost of their rides.
12
If network effects are
11
See Shannon Bond & Nicole Bullock, Uber IPO Prospectus Shows Ride-Hailing Revenues Stalled, FIN. TIMES
(Apr. 11, 2019), https://www.ft.com/content/c68d3662-5c76-11e9-939a-341f5ada9d40 (Uber “has lost $12bn from
its operations in total since 2014”); id. (“‘We will not shy away from making short-term financial sacrifices where
we see clear long-term benefits,’ wrote Dara Khosrowshahi, [Uber’s] chief executive.”); Megan McArdle, Uber and
Lyft Are Losing Money. At Some Point, We’ll Pay for It., W
ASH. POST (Mar. 5, 2019),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/uber-and-lyft-are-losing-money-at-some-point-well-pay-for-
it/2019/03/05/addd607c-3f95-11e9-a0d3-1210e58a94cf_story.html (In 2018, Lyft “lost more than $900 million after
expenses”).
12
See Izabella Kaminska, The Taxi Unicorn’s New Clothes, FIN. TIMES (Dec. 1, 2016),
https://ftalphaville.ft.com/2016/12/01/2180647/the-taxi-unicorns-new-clothes. Many of the paradigmatic firms of
the dot.com bubble also followed this strategy of subsidizing for growthoften sending the firm to oblivion. See
Greg Bensinger, In Kozmo.com’s Failure, Lessons for Same-Day Delivery, W
ALL ST. J. (Dec. 2, 2012),
https://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2012/12/03/in-kozmo-coms-failure-lessons-for-same-day-delivery.
17
strong, however, the market will tip in favor of one competitor, who then becomes the
monopolist.
5) Low Marginal and Distribution Costs
Digital goods often have low to zero marginal costs of expansion to another user, as mentioned
above. Distribution costs, one of the major expenses of expanding in a brick and mortar world,
are largely also zero on the internet. Indeed, poor internet infrastructure in the United States and
elsewhere may be the main distribution cost for many digital platforms.
13
Some digital platforms
do have positive distribution or marginal costs such as a piece of hardware, ecommerce
warehouses, or maintenance of scooters for example.
6) Global Reach
Lastly, many of the digital platforms we discuss in this report have a global reach. Those that are
focused on licensed digital content, rather than user-generated content, must negotiate licensing
and other legal issues in new jurisdictions. Reaching consumers in many languages is another
cost of expanding globally, as is dealing with local transportation regulations. However, the total
cost of expansion is generally lower than in traditional brick and mortar businesses.
ii. Barriers to Entry and Expansion
In this section, we explore the implications of the characteristics discussed above and the
possible effects of the increased market power created by barriers to entry. Outlined below are
some of the drivers that make market power more sustainable and disruption less likely in digital
markets.
1) Cost and Benefit Barriers to Entry
As mentioned above, network effects and scale economies are two significant barriers to entry.
The winner in these settings has a massive cost advantage from its scale of operations, and a
massive benefit advantage from the scale of its data. An entrant cannot generally overcome these
without either a similar installed base (network effects) or a similar scale (scale economies), both
of which are difficult to obtain quickly and cost-effectively. It is possible for an entrant to arrive
with scale and an installed base because it is a competing digital platform. Such entrants may
create effective competition for an incumbent platform that benefits consumers.
13
See, e.g., Drew FitzGerald, Facebook Looks to Build Underwater Ring Around Africa, WALL ST. J. (Apr. 7,
2019); Michael Sheetz, Here’s Why Amazon Is Trying to Reach Every Inch of the World With Satellites Providing
Internet, CNBC (Apr. 7, 2019), https://www.cnbc.com/2019/04/05/jeff-bezos-amazon-internet-satellites-4-billion-
new-customers.html; Press Release, Think Big With a Gig: Our Experimental Fiber Network, G
OOGLE (Feb. 10,
2010), https://googleblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/ultra-high-speed-broadband-is-coming-to.html.
18
Barriers to equivalent data resources, a side effect of not having the history, scale, or scope of the
incumbent, can inhibit entry, expansion, and innovation.
14
The same effects that drive the quality
of digital services higher as more users join—a positive feedback loop—makes the strong
stronger and the weak weaker.
15
Data feeds the development of algorithmic and AI training
processes that enables more profitable exploitation of consumer attention through advertising. A
data advantage over rivals can enable a company to achieve a virtuous circle of critical
economies of scale leading to network effects, and a competitive balance in its favor, leading to
the gathering of yet more data. A new entrant is likely to experience this in reverse—a vicious
cycleas it fails to surmount the entrance barrier.
Choosing a business model that is scalable, and has strong economies of scale, is of paramount
importance to creating entry barriers. A social media platform that chose to monitor harmful
content might need to hire many workers to keep ahead of users that game the algorithms. Hiring
workers is costly, slows down the ability to grow, and makes the platform less profitable both in
the short run and in the long run by limiting economies of scale. A platform aiming to tip the
market in its favor quickly will not choose this business model if it can gain consumers at lower
cost.
Because cost and benefit barriers are so powerful, digital platforms have powerful incentives to
pull slightly ahead of any rival. Due to the positive feedback loop described above, a small
advantage can turn into a large one. This powerful incentive to disadvantage a competitor raises
the possibility that some competitors will choose to violate the antitrust laws in order to stay
ahead. In general, to maintain or improve their competitive advantage, incumbents have strong
incentives to limit openness or interoperability and to be averse to data-portability policies. For
example, in a recent case, the upstart ethernet switch firm Arista alleged that the incumbent
Cisco encouraged openness and interoperability while it was dominant, but once a rival mounted
a serious challenge, claimed copyright protection on the previously open user interface, thus
cutting off the entrant from locked-in users.
16
14
The key themes below are discussed in greater detail in ARIEL EZRACHI & MAURICE E. STUCKE, VIRTUAL
COMPETITION: THE PROMISE AND PERILS OF THE ALGORITHM DRIVEN ECONOMY (2016). See also Ariel Ezrachi &
Maurice E. Stucke, Digitalisation and Its Impact on Innovation: Report Prepared for the European Commission
(DG Research & Innovation Working Paper, July 2018) (on file with authors).
15
See Data-Driven Innovation for Growth and Well-Being: Interim Synthesis Report, OECD (Oct. 2014),
http://www.oecd.org/sti/inno/data-driven-innovation-interim-synthesis.pdf, at 29 (citing C
ARL SHAPIRO & HAL R.
VARIAN, INFORMATION RULES: A STRATEGIC GUIDE TO THE NETWORK ECONOMY (1999)).
16
See Jan Wolfe, Arista to Pay $400 Million to Cisco to Resolve Court Fight, REUTERS (Aug. 6, 2018),
https://www.reuters.com/article/us-cisco-arista-settlement/arista-to-pay-400-million-to-cisco-to-resolve-court-fight-
idUSKBN1KR1PI; Don Clark, Arista Networks Files Antitrust Claims Against Cisco, W
ALL ST. J. (Jan. 25, 2016),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/arista-files-antitrust-charges-against-cisco-1453754642.
19
2) Barriers to Entry Created by Consumer Behavior
Market power is, ironically, generated by the very consumers who are harmed by it. Consumers
do not replace the default apps on their phones, do not scroll down to see more results, agree to
settings chosen by the service, and take other actions that may look like poor decisions if those
consumers like to choose among options and experience competition. Often the actions needed to
generate choice for the consumer seem trivial, such as a download and installation, opening
another app, or a few clicks. Consumers make these “mistakes” because of inherent behavioral
biases such as discounting the future too much and being too optimistic. The situation is worse
when the information needed to counteract bias is hard to obtain. For example, consumers tend
not to run the same search on a different search engine to compare the results, so they may never
find out the relative quality of the default search engine they use.
Research into behavioral biases and their consequences is several decades old and has already
produced ample and convincing evidence of the nature and existence of these biases on the part
of consumers. In 2002, Daniel Kahneman received the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for his
pioneering work on behavioral economics.
17
Fifteen years later, the Nobel Prize was awarded to
Richard Thaler in recognition of the progress of research in this domain and of the huge amount
of knowledge that has been produced.
18
In his Nobel lecture, Thaler pointed to the key insight from Kahneman and Amos Tversky:
people exhibit “bounded rationality,” meaning that in a complex world they use consistent rules
of thumb to make predictions and decisions. Thaler called on economists to use “psychological
realism” to improve their understanding of human decision making.
19
That psychological realism
combined with the economics toolkit produced the field of behavioral economics.
Behavioral economics has had a profound influence in the conduct of economic policy that will
become even more prevalent as more knowledge is digested and applied.
20
It is of great
relevance for our understanding of internet economics because, as information flows improve
and some physical barriers are removed, human factors are more likely to provide the frictions
that have increasing effects on market outcomes. These frictions in decision-making, and the fact
that consumers can be manipulated to take advantage of their biases, render consumers sticky
17
Daniel KahnemanFacts, NOBEL PRIZE (2019), https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/economic-
sciences/2002/kahneman/facts.
18
Richard ThalerFacts, NOBEL PRIZE (2019), https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/economic-
sciences/2017/thaler/facts.
19
Richard H. Thaler, From Cashews to Nudges: The Evolution of Behavioral Economics, 108 AMER. ECON. REV.
1265, 1266-1267 (2018).
20
See, e.g., Cass R. Sunstein, The Storrs Lectures: Behavioral Economics and Paternalism, 122 YALE L.J. 1826
(2013); Richard H. Thaler & Cass Sunstein, Libertarian Paternalism, 93 A
MER. ECON. REV. PAPERS &
PROCEEDINGS 175 (2003).
20
that is, people are slower to move to a superior product than they would be absent the
manipulation. This in turn makes demand less contestable and less favorable for an entrant.
One lesson from behavioral economics is that small differences (nudges) in how choices are
presented can have large effects on what choices people make.
21
A nudge to use a particular
browser as a default, for example, can entrench a platform’s browser. Another lesson is that
consumers overweight their immediate benefit relative to their welfare in the future. A consumer
searching for a solution to a particular problem will be inclined to click or use the first result or
recommendation, rather than searching on another page or scrolling down to examine many
listings. The tendency to choose in this manner entrenches the market power of the platform that
can control the display of content. Similarly, consumers’ preference for instant gratification may
lead them to sign away privacy rights they otherwise say they value.
22
This allows incumbent
platforms to gather data from these consumers that further entrenches their market position. In
general, the findings from behavioral economics demonstrate an under-recognized market power
held by incumbent digital platforms.
A second way consumers create entrenched market power is by single-homing. A multi-homing
user, for example, checks the price of a ride on both Uber and Lyft each time she needs a car. A
user that single-homes bestows market power on the platform she uses exclusively because
advertisers and other content providers can only get the user’s attention by going through that
platform. While users sometimes have the ability to employ multiple services, there is usually a
convenience cost to doing so. Making multi-homing easier will be a key element in encouraging
competition.
3) Barriers to Entry Created by an Incumbent Rival
Because platform market power is higher when users single-home, platforms try to get users to
do so. Sometimes this results in higher quality services: A mapping service can alert a user that it
will take 45 minutes to get to the airport when it sees a flight entry on the user’s calendar. If the
user buys those services from different platforms, she does not get the alert and experiences
lower quality. However, it is often possible for the data from one service to be read by a rival, so
platforms may also encourage single-homing by preventing interoperability.
21
See Thaler, supra note 19, at 1283.
22
See Alessandro Acquisiti et al., The Economics of Privacy, 54 J. ECON. LIT. 442 (2016); Alessandro Acquisti et
al., Privacy and Human Behavior in the Age of Information, 347 S
CIENCE MAG. 509, 510 (2015); Alessandro
Acquisiti, Privacy in Electronic Commerce and the Economics of Immediate Gratification (Fifth ACM Conference
on Electronic Commerce, 2004), https://www.cs.drexel.edu/~greenie/privacy/privacy-gratification.pdf; see also
Americans’ Attitudes About Privacy, Security, and Surveillance, P
EW RESEARCH CTR. (May 20, 2015),
https://www.pewresearch.org/wp-content/uploads/sites/9/2015/05/Privacy-and-Security-Attitudes-
5.19.15_FINAL.pdf, at 17 (reporting that 74% of survey respondents believe it is “very important” to be “in control
of who can get info about you”).
21
By limiting a rival’s access to data, dominant firms can make exclusive reliance on their service
either inevitable or the clearly best decision. Sharing data or allowing access to certain pieces of
information is often feasible at a technical level, but it is not normally in the interest of the
platform that could lose its users. For example, Google has been able to limit its users from
visiting (multi-homing on) competitors such as Yelp by displaying their information in the
search window directly.
23
To some extent, the limited switchability to the rival is driven by
asymmetric information in two places. First, consumers are generally not aware of, or attentive
to, the costs of failing to switch; for example, the quality of the content and the extent to which
the platform steers consumers to inferior content or product choices may be hard to see. Second,
there is often no way to compensate the consumer directly with lower prices—as an entrant such
as Warby Parker can do by selling eyeglasses directly to consumers at a lower pricebecause
the money price of services from a platform is often fixed at zero for both the incumbent and the
rival.
24
For all of these reasons, digital platform market power can become entrenched. The United
Kingdom, the European Commission, Australia, and Germany have all published reports
concluding that digital platforms’ market power has indeed become entrenched.
25
Surmounting
the existing barriers to entry created by consumer behavior, cost structure, public policy, and any
past anticompetitive conduct is extremely difficult. This fact has direct effects on consumers:
without entry or the credible threat of entry, digital platforms need not work hard to serve
consumers because they do not risk losing their consumers to a rival.
b. How Big Data Affects Digital Products and the Sale of
Advertisements
i. What Makes Data Big? And Does Big Data Harm
Consumers?
1) Targeted Advertising
Technology firms claim that they perform machine learning on big data, and that doing so gives
them both a competitive edge over rivals and allows them to better tailor their services to their
consumers. How might this work in practice? Consider a search engine with information about a
23
See Charles Duhigg, The Case Against Google, N.Y. TIMES MAG. (Feb. 20, 2018),
https://www.nytimes.com/2018/02/20/magazine/the-case-against-google.html
24
See, e.g., Competition Decision, Case COMP/AT.39740Google Search (June 27, 2017),
http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/cases/dec_docs/39740/39740_14996_3.pdf. Indeed, as the U.K.
Competition and Markets Authority has found, even in industries where prices exist but there are substantial search
frictions, consumers do not make choices that would give them substantial savings. See note 31, infra, and
associated text.
25
See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 75; EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 112;
A
USTRALIAN COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 35; GERMAN COMPETITION REPORT SUMMARY, supra note 1,
at 2.
22
given user’s search history, including the fact that this user recently searched for a specific pair
of Nike running shoes. The ad service can more effectively spend advertisers’ budgets by
showing the user ads focused on running-related products (or similar shoes to those the user
searched for). Advertisers will get a greater return on investment because more of their ads will
be shown to users who have demonstrated interest in running products—possibly very similar
running products to the ones being advertised. Moreover, users may actually prefer seeing ads
for other running products compared to more generic ads. The more personalized matching of
advertisement to potential customer would appear to help both the producer and consumer of the
advertisement.
This simplified example of personalized advertisement uses very little information about a
particular user (only that she had a particular search query) and little to nothing about other users
or another augmenting dataset, with the exception of a database of running-related items. Indeed,
this level of personalization could be similarly achieved in many low-tech spaces (e.g., running
products advertised in running magazines, whose readers have expressed interest in running
simply by reading the magazine). What is different about personalized advertisement if the ad
server has much more data at its disposal?
Box I
Platform vs. Brick-and-Mortar Advertising and Targeting
Traditional brick-and-mortar stores and online platforms differ greatly in their advertising and
personalization capabilities.
At the highest level, local grocers tend not to force shoppers to identify themselves when they
shop, rarely verify identification if used, and rarely have the ability to merge purchase history
with other detailed information from other aspects of their customers’ lives to design targeted
advertising. Online retailers, on the other hand, almost always require account creation for
purchasing, verify this information for each transaction, and have direct or easy access to
detailed non-shopping information about their customers.
Local grocery stores are capable of some data collection and personalization. For example, they
normally know that a majority of their customers live relatively close to the grocery store, so
they can rely on their knowledge about the general demographics of the neighborhood
population. The stores may also ask that consumers use a loyalty card to receive discounts,
which then allows them to track per-customer purchasing patterns, offer particular customers
with certain purchasing patterns particular coupons or free products, and see the result of such
offers on a user’s purchase history. Nonetheless, the effectiveness of these methods is limited
in comparison to digital shops. Consumers normally retain the option to buy full-priced
groceries without tracking (pay in cash), or to intermittently switch their cards with other
people they know (for example). More importantly, even if grocers used fingerprints or other
unique identifiers to remove the possibility of anonymity, the data they would track would still
be entirely comprised of grocery purchase history for its customers.
23
2) Dimensions Along Which Data Can Be Big
In order to discuss the use-cases of large-scale datasets in online personalized advertising, it
helps to define in what sense a dataset can be big. Big data commonly refers to two very
different properties of a dataset: either that the dataset has many people’s data in it, or that the
dataset has a great deal of information about each person in the dataset. For simplicity we refer to
the former as “large population datasets” and the latter as “high dimensional data.” These distinct
ways in which a dataset can be big enable very different uses.
Large population datasets allow the possessor to infer both unknown attributes of current users,
and statistical facts about individuals not currently in the dataset. If the dataset contains many
instances of users’ queries along with their locations at the time they made those queries, an
advertiser could use future users’ locations to help predict what those users might search for or
be interested in seeing advertisements about. Numerous statistical techniques can be used to
show that, for a large population dataset, simple statistics that hold true on the dataset should also
hold true for fresh users, assuming they come from a similar pool as those in the dataset. For
example, if 30% of queries in the database originating from Cape Cod searched for lobster rolls,
there is a 30% chance that a query made by a future user based in Cape Cod will be for lobster
rolls, assuming the user is visiting in a similar time frame that the dataset was gathered in,
arrived at the search engine in a manner similar to other dataset users, and the number of queries
in the dataset originating in Cape Code is sufficiently large. If the dataset has many queries but
Platform vs. Brick-and-Mortar Advertising and Targeting (Cont.)
This limitation does not apply to digital platforms. Online groceries require a customer to make
an account prior to allowing any purchase. Thus, all purchases belong to a particular account,
which also contains identifying information about a customer including their search history,
billing, shipping, and email addresses. This ensures that (potentially) all search history and all
purchases sent to a particular address (or paid for with a certain mailing address) can be collated
and analyzed by the seller and used to design offers or other services for a customer. If this
seller has a broader set of services than just grocery retail (for example, the seller is Google or
Amazon), the information they can collate together with this purchase history might include
email transcripts, calendar information, or search and purchase history of non-grocery products,
amongst others. All of this information can allow for much more aggressive marketing to a
particular consumer, based on many aspects of their lives beyond their historical grocery
shopping habits.
A grocery store can take advantage of hungry shoppers by placing a
representative selection of junk food in the checkout line. A digital platform, by contrast, can
design an individualized tempting “checkout offer based on that
particular consumer’s
purchase history, current behavior, time of day,
and the emotional content of recent
communications.
24
fairly few from Cape Cod, statistical techniques will provide lower confidence in their ability to
predict future queries emanating from Cape Cod.
High-dimensional datasets allow for different uses than large-population datasets do. Suppose a
dataset contains only a few users, but each user’s entry contains their entire email history. A
quick read of a user’s recent emails could give an advertiser a very clear window into what that
user might be looking to purchase. The richness of a given user’s data entry can describe in great
detail many facts about her, including her future travel itineraries, plans for large purchases,
information about her career and social networks, and so forth. Looking only at that user's
information, a deft advertiser could likely select any number of products this user would be much
more likely than an average person to find interesting. Hotels in Cape Cod would much prefer to
advertise to a user if her recent emails describe travel plans to Cape Cod. However, if only three
or four users belong to the dataset, an advertiser can learn very little about new users from
studying the rich but poorly-populated dataset; again, statistical techniques have much lower
confidence when the datasets they operate on are small.
The most useful datasets, from the perspective of an advertiser or other service provider, are
large in both senses: they contain rich information about a huge number of people. This is even
more true when the rich information contains different types of data, for example, email,
location, and search queries. A dataset of this type allows the provider to both learn high-level
population statistics (for which it needs a large population in its dataset) and to carefully tailor its
ads to each individual in its dataset (because it has very rich information about users in the
dataset). Even more interestingly, the complexity of population-level statements one can make
from such a dataset increases. This occurs both because each user's data has more dimensions, so
there are more relevant hypotheses to explore, and because as the number of users in the dataset
grows, so does the statistical significance of any particular statement that holds for the dataset.
3) Accuracy (and Utility) May Display Increasing Returns
Entrants could have an opportunity if marginal returns were to fall as providers’ datasets grow,
because the incumbent’s marginal cost of acquiring new data would eventually exceed the
marginal value. But a simple model shows this may not be the case. Given a fixed dataset of a
particular number n of individuals with a certain number k of features (also referred to as
attributes), the dataset owner does not face decreasing marginal returns with respect to either n or
k.
26
Why might datasets show increasing marginal returns in either the number of features or the
number of rows already present in the dataset? For a formal treatment of this question, please see
the discussion below which works out in detail a particular example in the advertising domain.
26
This holds even in “natural” settings, where each member of the dataset is drawn identically from a normal
distribution.
25
Informally, imagine you are trying to sell a service to people who live in Manhattan and are
planning a wedding. Knowing either that a person lives in Manhattan, or that they are planning a
wedding, may make almost no difference in determining their willingness to use the service
because both are very low-probability events, while having both pieces of information together
allows the Manhattan wedding planner to easily pinpoint interested consumers. More generally,
as a firm accumulates more information about more people, its marginal returns to new data need
not fall.
This last point helps us understand why data has increasing marginal returns. Even if the dataset
is large enough that it allows a company to make accurate inferences about a given population,
the company will always benefit from having specific information about a given individual,
allowing it to become more and more confident about what the consumer wants, and to better
tailor its services and ads.
Companies therefore have no incentives to stop looking for and accumulating new pieces of data,
entrenching incumbents with large datasets vis-à-vis entrants with smaller databases. Consumers
on the internet leave numerous traces of their activities across a range of applications (for
example, their location, what they buy, who they talk to, and what they say), and technology
allows platforms to identify and analyze these traces. The amount of data on individual behavior
that can be collected, merged, analyzed, and stored is rising, and the combination of different
dimensions of data generates valuable information about individuals’ tastes and behaviors. As
individuals rely more and more on a platform to organize their lives through their online social,
cultural, or economic activity, their data become more informative about their future choices and
firms are willing to pay to influence those choices. Furthermore, the emergence of the Internet of
Things means that platforms will have access to yet more data generated by home appliances,
cars, and other devices. Indeed, consumers’ devices can now track eye movement, mouse
movement, body movement, and body position. In parallel with the evolution of the internet that
made tracking of billions of individuals possible, advances in data mining and artificial
intelligence have enabled firms to learn more from data than was conceivable a few decades
ago.
27
Many digital markets have tipped and therefore there are only a few entrenched platforms able to
gather this breadth of data. As Alessandro Acquisti and colleagues concluded in a recent study,
“a few ‘gatekeeper’ firms [will be left] in a position to control the tracking and linking of . . .
behaviors across platforms, online services, and sites.”
28
When data exhibit increasing returns to
27
Jaron Lanier, a creator of virtual reality, has warned of the problems associated with a “surveillance economy” in
which users of digital tools and platforms would be enticed to give up personal data in exchange for “free” products
and access. See J
ARON LANIER, WHO OWNS THE FUTURE? (2013). The data, Lanier argues, could then be monetized
by the owners of the platforms and applications, largely through the sale of the data to advertisers and others finding
value in the users’ personal characteristics and proclivities.
28
Acquisti et al., supra note 22, at 444.
26
dimensionality and size, platforms that can track many users across those dimensions will have
economies of scale and scope; they will be able to sell more valuable advertising.
Nonetheless, this targeting can also raise the quality of services provided by platforms. When
they can identify individual tastes at fine levels and personalize their services to this taste, they
often improve people’s lives. Search engines can better answer queries or find a nearby
destination, cultural and news websites are able to suggest well-suited content, and ecommerce
websites can improve matching between buyers and sellers. These are all part of the consumer
benefit described previously.
4) Types of Data
The definition of what constitutes a consumer’s data can become complicated. Suppose the
consumer’s data and those of similar consumers allowed the service to infer characteristics about
the consumer (for example, that she has a tattoo) without any action or communication on the
topic by the consumer. Is this piece of information part of the “consumer’s” data, or is it the
intellectual property of the algorithm owner?
The Vestager Report and the Furman Report categorize data as volunteered , observed, or
inferred. Volunteered data is intentionally provided by the user to the service -- for example,
when a user provides their favorite TV shows to a service in order to receive recommendations.
Observed data, such as the history of shows that the consumer actually watches, are
automatically gathered by a service. Some observed data may not be intentionally provided by
users if they do not understand the privacy protections in the service -- for example, location
tracking of a person using a video app. Finally, the service can process volunteered and observed
data to infer additional information about the user or a group of users.
29
We include (but do not
always distinguish among) all these types of data in this report’s discussions.
29
See EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 25. Famously, Target claims to have been able to predict a
customer’s pregnancy before she knew about it. See Charles Duhigg, How Companies Learn Your Secrets, N.Y.
T
IMES (Feb. 16, 2012), https://www.nytimes.com/2012/02/19/magazine/shopping-habits.html.
27
Box II
Why Data Has Increasing Marginal Returns
For a particular dataset, suppose the first feature is the one the owner wants to predict for
future users. For example, this feature might refer to whether or not a user will book a
particular hotel if shown an advertisement for it. If k=2, and the second feature represents the
home zip code of a user, there might be some limited ability to predict interest in a hotel
based on this zip code being sufficiently far from the hotel. If k=3, consider the case where
the third feature refers to the annual household income of each person.
With both zip code and income available, we can express much more complex prediction
rules for interest in hotel X. For example, we could predict that a user will book the hotel if
 +  ,
for some α, β, γ 0. If the true relationship between these three features is in fact linear, then
the utility of gathering the income variable will be marginally decreasing in the set of other
(linearly relevant) features.
However, it might be that the best prediction of whether a hotel will be booked is a nonlinear
function of distance and income; perhaps a person will book exactly when they live far
enough away and make at least a certain amount of money:
 and 
where users with distance > α and income > β make up 10% of the distribution. Suppose 40%
of the users have distance > α, and 40% of the users have income > β.
28
ii. Data Control and Ownership
1) Status Quo
In the United States at present, a consumer has no property or control rights over their data. This
stands in contrast to Europe, where the GDPR sets a standard for what a digital business can do
with a consumer’s data.
Why Data Has Increasing Marginal Returns (Cont.)
Knowing a user’s zip code (and corresponding distance) gives some limited ability to predict
when both the income and distance are sufficiently large, but knowing both the zip code and
income will allow them to perfectly predict the 10% of the population that might have
interest in staying at the hotel. For this reason, the utility of data owners need not be
marginally decreasing in the set of features they have.
To be explicit, fix an advertising firm for the hotel. If the advertising firm purchases the
ability to see each potential advertisee’s zip code, then showing the advertisement to
customers as a function of their distance is now possible. For example, the advertiser could
only show the advertisement to customers whose distance is more than β, increasing the
probability that the ad is shown to an interested party from 10% to 25%. If the firm then
acquired the ability to estimate each advertisee’s income, it could use both features together
and only show the advertisement to customers with both income > α and distance > β.
This would raise the probability that a targeted advertisee would be interested in the ad from
25% to 100%. The two features are otherwise identical, and so it would also be the case that
first acquiring income and then distance would raise the probability of an advertisement
reaching an interested customer from 10% to 25% to 100% if one started with no features,
then added income, then distance. Therefore, the utility increase which comes from adding
distance first is .15 * (value of showing the ad to an interested customer), while the utility
increase from adding distance after first acquiring income is .75 * (value of showing the ad to
an interested customer). That is, the distance feature is more valuable after first learning
about income (and vice versa). This shows that the value of features may not be marginally
decreasing in the set of features accrued thus far.
One can also use the same sort of relationship to argue that the dataset owner's utility need not
be marginally decreasing in n, the number of people in the dataset. Again, suppose one can
only predict interest in the hotel with the conjunction of zip code and income information, but
that this relationship is not a priori known to the dataset owner, and they are instead trying to
learn how to predict hotel interest based on a dataset they have available to them. Using
statistical techniques, it wont be possible to learn rules of this form (if x and y then z) to a high
degree of accuracy unless the dataset has sufficiently large n. The utility of adding additional
people to the dataset can increase as the dataset grows, depending on the owner's utility for
accuracy of the learned model.
29
In the U.K., regulators have sought to give consumers useful control over their financial data.
After a lengthy investigation showed that consumers rarely switch banks despite large gains to
doing so, regulators sought to use Open Banking to give people the ability to seamlessly move
between banks.
30
The Open Banking Initiative allows consumers to obtain, see, and transmit
their banking activity in a standardized and secure fashion to regulated and approved third-party
firms.
31
This is an example of data portability. Theory suggests that consumers will use that
power to move their business to banks that lower prices and improve services. If Open Banking
causes more competitive outcomes, it may provide a strong model for regulated portability and
interoperability in other markets.
32
The Vestager Report defines protocol interoperability and
data interoperability as stronger than data portability because they allow continuing
communication between two services. It defines full protocol interoperability as a complete
linking of the two services in a way that reduces network effects. We will return to these
concepts below.
Data intermediaries collect consumers’ information that they then sell to third parties. These
intermediaries may be large websites obtaining the information through their service to
consumers, or data brokers. Data have specific features that make this market unusual. For
example, data are “non-rivalrous” meaning a broker can sell the same dataset to many buyers and
still retain it, unlike, for example, the sale of apples. Once you’ve sold an apple, you’re out an
apple; once you’ve sold a given piece of information to one buyer, you can sell it again to
another buyer. A key feature of data in this context is that data may be either directly shared with
the buyer, or withheld (to prevent the buyer from achieving its own economies of scale and
scope) but embedded into a service the buyer wants, such as targeting advertising.
33
30
See Alasdair Smith et al., RETAIL BANKING MARKET INVESTIGATION: FINAL REPORT, U.K. COMPETITION &
MARKETS AUTHORITY (Aug. 2016),
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/57ac9667e5274a0f6c00007a/retail-banking-market-investigation-full-
final-report.pdf, at xiii-xiv.
31
See U.K. COMPETITION & MARKETS AUTHORITY, THE RETAIL BANKING MARKET INVESTIGATION ORDER 2017
(2017),
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/600842/retail-
banking-market-investigation-order-2017.pdf; see also O
PEN BANKING LTD., OPEN BANKING: GUIDELINES FOR
PARTICIPANTS (2018), https://www.openbanking.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/Guidelines-for-Open-Data-
Participants.pdf; Rowland Manthorpe, What is Open Banking and PSD2? WIRED Explains, W
IRED (Apr. 17, 2018),
https://www.wired.co.uk/article/open-banking-cma-psd2-explained. Third party firms that customers can elect to
give data access are regulated and approved by the Financial Conduct Authority. See Press Release, U.K. Fin.
Conduct Auth., FCA Finalises Revised Payment Services Directive (PSD2) Requirements (Sept. 9, 2017),
https://www.fca.org.uk/news/press-releases/fca-finalises-revised-psd2-requirements.
32
There are some signs that Open Banking has seen early success. See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at
70.
33
See Dirk Bergemann & Alessandro Bonatti, The Wild West of Information Markets: What We Need to Know
Before Law and Order Can Rule, V
OX (Oct. 11, 2018), https://voxeu.org/article/wild-west-information-markets;
Dirk Bergemann & Alessandro Bonatti, Markets for information: An Introduction, (Cowles Foundation Discussion
Paper No. 2142, Aug. 29, 2018), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3240310.
30
2) Externalities
What can a person do with ownership over her data? The previous section describes two ways in
which data might be used: First, it might be used to tailor services to a given person; second, it
might be used to learn patterns that hold on average for the population from which the dataset
was drawn. The former does not necessarily transfer any knowledge about one customer to the
treatment of another, while the latter aims to learn about some fraction of a dataset and use that
information to affect interactions with future customers. Note that this use of data creates
externalities between consumers. Purchase or travel patterns by one person are used to create
recommendations or suggestions for similar people, where “similar” is determined by machine
learning. For this reason, the value of an individual person’s data is more than the value of using
it to market to them. A customer whose data predicts the behavior of many other consumers is
very valuable to a platform.
3) Deletions
One might simplistically think that “owning” one’s own data gives a person the ability or right to
delete it. The ease with which a customer’s data can truly be deleted depends on the way the firm
has created and is using that data. If a user’s own data is used only to personalize her experience,
deleting her data will mean that the datasetand the service’s subsequent behavior—has no
trace of the customer ever belonging to the dataset. If, however, the service used the customer’s
data to inform population-wide behavior (by analyzing the dataset including this customer and
storing the results of those analyses), merely deleting the customer’s data from the dataset does
not truly erase her presenceher data will still have a lasting effect on the future behavior of the
service.
For example, suppose the service scans the dataset for one representative user from each zip code
and remembers the purchasing history of each representative user. Even if the service removes
the initial entry corresponding to a particular user in the original dataset, if the service still uses
this set of representative users’ purchasing histories, some of the user’s data can still remain in
the system. While this example may seem contrived, many machine learning methods do some
amount of memorization of some subset of their training data.
34
Beyond memorization, there are other, more subtle ways in which a user’s data can affect the
long-term behavior of a system and what information the system holds on to. The natural tool to
restrict how much a system’s information is affected by one user’s data is to impose differential
privacy. Loosely speaking, differential privacy restricts the statistics created from the dataset to
not reveal if any particular person or observation is in the dataset.
34
For example, support vector machines are explicitly recorded as a small number of datapoints on which the model
was learned.
31
4) Transparency, Choice, and Fraud
According to the Federal Trade Commission, the market for data suffers from a lack of
transparency.
35
Most consumers have no idea how much information is being collected about
them, sold, and used to make a profit.
36
One way in which digital platforms exploit their market
power is by requiring consumers to agree to terms and conditions that are unclear, difficult to
understand, and constantly changing. The terminology in these contracts is legal and the
documents are often lengthy; the consequence of the different clauses is difficult to understand
and foresee. Moreover, the user of a device or platform makes a choice to sink investments
(posts, calendars, media, and so on) in a particular platform at a moment in time when a
particular user agreement is in force. After the device or platform updates its terms of service, a
user may be locked in. Having bought a phone, they won’t immediately want to switch; having
built a network of friends, they often won’t want to leave. Thus, the user does not have the same
set of choices as she did the first time she hit “agree,” and some agencies have argued this is no
longer a free choice.
37
Lastly, a digital platform may describe its data-use policy in its terms of
service and then deviate from that, rendering the initial statement fraudulent.
38
35
FED. TRADE COMMN, DATA BROKERS: A CALL FOR TRANSPARENCY AND ACCOUNTABILITY: A REPORT OF THE
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION (2014), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/data-brokers-call-
transparency-accountability-report-federal-trade-commission-may-2014/140527databrokerreport.pdf.
36
See id. at 42.
37
See Press Release, Bundeskartellamt, Bundeskartellamt Prohibits Facebook from Combining User Data from
Different Sources (Feb. 7, 2019),
https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Meldung/EN/Pressemitteilungen/2019/07_02_2019_Facebook.html
(determining that Facebook’s take-it-or-leave-it under agreements constitute “abuse of market power”).
38
See, e.g., Tony Romm & Elizabeth Dwoskin, U.S. Regulators Have Met to Discuss Imposing a Record-Setting
Fine Against Facebook for Privacy Violations, W
ASH. POST (Jan. 18, 2019),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2019/01/18/us-regulators-have-met-discuss-imposing-record-setting-
fine-against-facebook-some-its-privacy-violations.
Box III
Digital Identities
Perhaps the next major shift in digital competition will be the quest to control the identification
market. Once we create an account with any digital platform, we create a digital identity which
incorporates select data on age, sex, address, email address, preferences, and, frequently, much
more. These digital identities help companies identify and tag users to the data they generate,
be it transactional, social, simple web navigation or even meta data. Digital identities work like
access and tracking mechanisms, allowing a user to surpass a wall in exchange for enabling the
company to link the data to a given dataset (e.g., using a Facebook login to access a website).
Identity data and control is highly valuable and platforms can monetize it in many ways. They
can use it to personalize services and charge subscription fees, provide advertising or market
intelligence, or as a way to increase bottleneck power and charge companies for user access .
The more privacy protection technologies grow and limit widespread data collection online, the
more being the single identification point for users will grow in importance and value.
32
iii. Digital Platforms are Characterized by Free Services
“Free” is not a special zone where economics or antitrust do not apply.
39
A free good is one
where the seller has chosen to set a monetary price of zero and may set other, non-monetary,
conditions or duties. Zero is a number, just like 10 is a number. If a competitive price is $10
while the realized price is $15, there is a $5 markup above the competitive price. This is the same
harm the consumer bears when the competitive price is -$5 (at this price the digital platform is
actually paying the consumer for her data and information in addition to providing her with
services) and the realized price is $0.
Barter is a common way in which consumers pay for digital services. They barter their privacy
and information about what restaurants they would like to eat in and what goods they would like
to buy in exchange for digital services. The platform then sells targeted advertising, which is
made valuable by the bartered information. But, in principle, that information has a market price.
It is not easy to see if the value of any one consumer’s information is exactly equal to the value
of the services she receives from the platform. However, many digital platforms are enormously
profitable, and have been for many years, which suggests that in aggregate we do know the
answer: the information is more valuable than the cost of the services. The economics literature
has modeled this setting and is able to define a data markup.
40
The current inability to use both positive and negative prices for digital goods means that the
policy discussion cannot focus on dollars alone as the unit of cost. Rather, digital platforms
should be analyzed using both price and quality. “Quality-adjusted price” is a metric often used
by economists in this situation. If a platform’s price is fixed at zero and the quality of the service
improves, then its quality-adjusted price has fallen. Conversely, if a platform’s price remains
zero but its quality falls, its quality-adjusted price has risen. When the price is fixed at zero, it is
possible to track quality-adjusted price over time: the movement in quality accurately reflects
quality-adjusted price.
41
Online platforms offer many services for zero monetary price while they try to raise participation
in order to generate advertising revenue. Free services are prevalent on the internet in part
39
See, for example, the current head of the U.S. Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division describing the challenge
faced by his division of defining markets when goods are free. Makan Delrahim, U.S. Assistant Att’y General, “I’m
Free”: Platforms and Antitrust Enforcement in the Zero-Price Economy, Address at Silicon Flatirons Annual
Technology Policy Conference at The University of Colorado Law School (Feb. 11, 2019),
https://www.justice.gov/opa/speech/assistant-attorney-general-makan-delrahim-delivers-keynote-address-silicon-
flatirons (arguing, without regard for quality effects, that traditional antitrust market definition cannot work because
“[w]e cannot look at the effects of a five percent increase in price because five percent of zero is still zero”). See
also id. (arguing that “[c]hoosing variables for measuring market shares also can be more complicated where shares
of revenue is not an option”).
40
See Dirk Bergemann et al., The Design and Price of Information, 108 AMER. ECON. REV. 1 (2018).
41
The European Commission has noted the importance of assessing product quality in zero-price settings. See
Samson Y Esayas, Competition in (Data) Privacy: ‘Zero’-Price Markets, Market Power, and the Role of
Competition Law, 8 I
NT. DATA PRIVACY L. 181 (2018).
33
because internet firms can harness multi-sided network externalities. While the low price can be
a blessing for consumers, it has drawbacks for competition and market structure in a world where
institutions have not arisen to manage negative prices. Because there is currently no convenient
way to pay consumers with money, platforms are able to mark up the competitive price all the
way to zero. This constraint can effectively eliminate price competition, shifting the competitive
process to quality and the ability of each competitor to generate network externalities. Depending
on the context this may favor or impede entry of new products. For example, entry will be
encouraged when a price of zero leads to supra-competitive profits, and impeded when a zero
price prevents entrants from building a customer base through low price. Moreover, unlike
traditional markets where several quality layers may coexist at different price levels (provided
that some consumers favor lower quality at low price), markets where goods are free will be
dominated by the best quality firm and others may compete only in so far as they can
differentiate their offers and target different customers. This strengthens the firm’s incentive to
increase quality through increasing fixed costs in order to attract customers (known as the Sutton
sunk cost effect) and further pushes the market toward a concentrated market structure.
42
It is a puzzle that, to date, no entrepreneur or business has found a way to pay consumers for
their data in money. For example, a consumer’s wireless carrier could aggregate micropayments
across all manner of digital destinations and apply the credit to her bill each month. It may be
that adverse selection, transaction costs, and coordination difficulties create too large a barrier
for today’s entrepreneurs, though technical solutions like a verifiable digital identity, mentioned
above, would combat adverse selection.
43
Furthermore, a carrier that could bargain effectively
with platforms on behalf of its subscribers for high payments would likely gain subscribers.
Notice that an easy method to pay consumers, combined with price competition for those
consumers, might significantly erode the high profits of many incumbent platforms. Platforms
likely have no economic incentive to work diligently to operationalize negative prices.
42
See SUTTON, supra note 7.
43
See ERIC A. POSNER & E. GLEN WEYL, RADICAL MARKETS: UPROOTING CAPITALISM AND DEMOCRACY FOR A
JUST SOCIETY (2018).
34
III. PROBLEMS ARISING IN DIGITAL MARKETS
The changing market dynamics, outlined above, raise doubts about the market’s ability to ensure
ongoing innovation and competition. Increased concentration levels, market power, network
effects, and control over data and analytics have in many digital markets tipped the market in
favor of the incumbents.
The theme we return to throughout this report is the difficulty of entry into digital platform
businesses once an incumbent is established. Whether the entrant is vertical or horizontal, has
succeeded to some degree, is nascent, or is a potential entrant, its existence improves consumer
welfare. Either the entrant provides more choice, different features, and a chance of higher
quality, or the threat of those outcomes spurs the incumbent to provide lower prices, higher
quality and innovation, and to do so more quickly.
By focusing on this feature of digital platforms, we are highlighting the cause of the market
power, not its result. Absent entry barriers of the type discussed above, the tremendous amount
of profit available in these markets would stimulate entry. Protecting competition in these
markets requires protecting competitors. Entry and potential entry create more competitors (in
expectation), and that increase depends on competition working effectively so that a meritorious
entrant can successfully dethrone the incumbent.
The categories of economic harms to consumer welfare from digital platforms are the standard
ones: price, quality, and innovation. The report will primarily emphasize quality and innovation
harms due to their greater complexity and generality. For example, by excluding competitors,
dominant firms do not need to innovate as hard as they otherwise would be required to keep their
customers. Likewise, when platforms do not face competition, they will be able to reduce
quality, for example, by decreasing privacy protections, without losing customers or revenue.
44
When a service reduces quality without lowering price, it is raising quality-adjusted prices,
which harms consumers. For example, if a phone service were to lower the quality of service but
keep monthly fees the same, it would have raised quality-adjusted price. Because many digital
services are purchased with barter, the monetary price paid by consumers is zero, and quality-
adjusted prices cannot be directly seen the way a nominal price can be. On the advertiser side of
the platform, where monetary prices are charged, harms to competition exist in the more
ordinary form of higher markups for ads and other services. These markups are eventually paid
by consumers because they are built in to the prices of the goods and services that are advertised
online.
44
See Agustín Reyna, The Psychology of PrivacyWhat Can Behavioural Economics Contribute to Competition in
Digital Markets?, 8 I
NT. DATA PRIVACY L. 240 (2018).
35
a. Quality Harms
i. Personal Data and Behavioral Economics
1) Behavioral Economics
As discussed above, behavioral economics helps improve our understanding of real consumer
choices and suggests that consumer exploitation is common. There are a number of systematic
consumer biases that, when incorporated into economic analysis, affect outcomes and welfare.
For instance, individuals can be subject to salience effects, putting excessive weight on the most
salient information. Confirmation bias can lead them to change their preferences to conform with
past choices.
45
Consumers are often biased toward the status quo even when it is no longer
optimal.
46
Perhaps the most important consumer biases are impatience and lack of self-control.
The former refers to the discounting of any payoff that occurs further in the future than the
present. The latter is closely related and refers to the extent to which individuals fail to resist
short-term impulses in order to achieve long-term goals. The literature in behavioral antitrust
argues that status quo, salience, and impatience are the most relevant for antitrust analysis.
47
Platforms that analyze their consumers’ behavior can exploit these biases by framing choices to
make certain information salient, designing a status quo that is profitable, inducing addictive
behaviors, generating sales through impulsive consumption, and exploiting consumers’
disinclination to search. These strategies are common in the brick and mortar world. For
example, the candy aisle in supermarket check-out lines, or the rug store that has a special 50%-
off sale every day.
2) Using Machine Learning to Take Advantage of Consumers
There are now decades of economic research demonstrating consumer bias and firm responses in
offline markets.
48
For example, gyms offer subscription memberships rather than pay-per-visit
45
Confirmation Bias, WIKIPEDIA (Mar. 22, 2019), https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Confirmation_bias (“Confirmation
bias is the tendency to search for, interpret, favor, and recall information in a way that confirms one's preexisting
beliefs or hypotheses.”); see, e.g., Thaler, supra note 19, at 1266 (“People guess that in the United States today gun
deaths by homicide are more frequent than gun deaths by suicide, although the latter are about twice as common.
The bias comes because homicides are more publicized than suicides, and thus more ‘available’ in memory.”).
46
William Samuelson & Richard Zeckhauser, Status Quo Bias in Decision Making, 1 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 7, 8
(1988) (“[D]ecision makers exhibit a significant status quo bias. Subjects in our experiments adhered to status quo
choices more frequently than would be predicted by the canonical model.”).
47
See Amelia Fletcher, The EU Google Decisions: Extreme Enforcement or the Tip of the Behavioral Iceberg?,
C
OMPETITION POL. INT. ANTITRUST CHRON. (Jan. 2019), https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/wp-
content/uploads/2019/01/CPI-Fletcher.pdf.
48
See, e.g., DANIEL KAHNEMAN & THOMAS GILOVICH, HEURISTICS AND BIASES: THE PSYCHOLOGY OF INTUITIVE
JUDGMENT (2002); Nicholas Barberis & Richard Thaler, A Survey of Behavioral Finance, in HANDBOOK OF THE
ECONOMICS OF FINANCE (René M. Stulz & George Constantinides eds., 2003); see also, e.g., Daniel Kahneman,
Jack L. Knetsch, & Richard H. Thaler, Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias, 5 J.
ECON. PERSP. 193 (1991).
36
knowing that members will not come as often as they anticipate,
49
and credit cards offer teaser
rates knowing that consumers plan to have no debt in 6 months’ time.
50
However, the strategies
firms have used to date are swamped by what digital businesses can learn by using high-
dimensional, large datasets to explore every nook and cranny of consumers’ many behavioral
shortcomings and biases in real time. This strategy is of serious concern when combined with an
understanding of the digital platform business model discussed above. The platform’s goal is to
use its knowledge of consumers, combined with its market power (and the resulting lack of
consumer choice), to extract profit. Some of that profit may come from value creation, or
“expanding the pie,” but some will come from transfers to the platform from both the consumer
side and the advertiser side. Because individuals are subject to behavioral biases, consumers are
vulnerable to a platform’s exploitative behavior. Additionally, when individuals are workers, as
they often are in the “gig” economy, these tools can be used to advantage the platform against
the worker.
Digital businesses not only have more information than traditional firms, but they have more
variations of products or services and the ability to control the environment and the timing of
choices and offers. For example, a firm can hide a component of a good’s price to let consumers
discover prices only once they have invested significant time and effort into buying the good.
This strategy can be differentially employed depending on the consumer’s past willingness to
pay. Framing, nudges, and defaults can direct a consumer to the choice that is most profitable for
the platform. A platform can analyze a user’s data in real time to determine when she is in an
emotional “hot state” and offer a good that the user would not purchase when her self-control
was higher. Consider a supercomputer tracking a consumer, via her cell phone, around the town
until she is tired and frustrated in some way, and at that moment presenting her ads and
information about junk food. This type of exploitation could depend on input from devices such
as eye-tracking sensors, the ability of AI to understand the emotion expressed in texts and email,
and all the other data the platform has about the consumer combined at a very large scale. This
same tactic can be used to gain advantage against an independent contractor, e.g. a driver, whose
behavior and location can be tracked for long periods.
51
In addition, machine learning applied to
big data may help differentiate well-informed and sophisticated consumers or workers from
poorly informed or more naïve consumers, raising the possibility of further exploitation of those
least prepared to resist it.
Internet firms make frequent use of digital defaults, framings, and nudges. When a user is
signing up for a new service, the sign-up form may automatically check the box that permits the
service to send the user emails.
52
A user can opt-out of receiving emails by unchecking the box,
49
See Stefano DellaVigna & Ulrike Malmendier, Paying Not to Go to the Gym, 96 AMER. ECON. REV. 694 (2006).
50
See Oren Bar-Gill & Ryan Bubb, Credit Card Pricing: The CARD Act and Beyond, 97 CORNELL L. REV. 967
(2012).
51
https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2017/04/02/technology/uber-drivers-psychological-tricks.html
52
This is no longer permitted in the European Union. See Regulation (EU) 2016/679 of the European Parliament and
the Council of 27 April 2016 on the Protection of Natural Persons with Regard to the Processing of Personal Data
37
but doing so is harder than sticking with the default. The results of a search that fits onto one
page may all be sponsored, whereas finding the organic links requires paging down. Homo
economicus is hardly influenced by defaults—to a rational agent, scrolling down or unchecking a
box is trivial—but real people are influenced. Nudges are not unique to digital products; for
example, an employer offering a default health care plan to its employees nudges employees
towards choosing that plan—employees can select a different plan, but doing so is harder than
sticking with the default.
53
What is noteworthy, however, is the platform’s detailed,
personalized, minute-by-minute control over their interface. This control enables platforms to
create a façade of competition, choice, and autonomy when in fact users are being directed with
behavioral techniques.
54
With big data and machine learning, firms are able to understand and manipulate individual
preferences at a scale that goes far beyond what is possible in traditional markets. This capability
is qualitatively new. The environment is characterized by extreme asymmetries of information
and analytical capacity between the platform and the user. This enables firms to charge higher
prices (for goods purchased and for advertising) and engage in behavioral discrimination,
allowing platforms to extract more value from users where they are weak.
55
The problem is only
growing; platforms continue to make investments to extract data, encourage stickiness and
addiction, and promote ever-greater use, in order to run data analytics and enable more precise
targeting.
56
The economic literature suggests that competition by itself cannot resolve the issue raised by the
exploitation of behavioral biases or poor consumer information. This is because staying
profitable in a competitive environment may force firms to exploit behavioral bias to achieve
maximal profitability. Firms abstaining from doing so may be driven out of the market. Rather,
competition causes a shift of surplus to wiser consumers; profit from exploitation of biased
consumers is used to compete for well-informed consumers. For consumers who can guard
against exploitation, there are therefore significant gains to be had from competition. But this
and on the Free Movement of Such Data, and Repealing Directive 95/46/EC (General Data Protection Regulation),
2016 O.J. (L 119/1), § 32 (“Silence, pre-ticked boxes or inactivity should not . . . constitute consent.”).
53
Thaler, supra note 19, at 1283. Default settings have very large effects, for example, in voluntary organ donation
decisions. Countries with an op-in default generally have the vast majority of the nation’s adults enrolled to donate,
while countries with default opt-out decisions see the opposite result. See Eric J. Johnson & Daniel Goldstein, Do
Defaults Save Lives?, 302 S
CIENCE 1338 (2003).
54
See ARIEL EZRACHI & MAURICE E. STUCKE, VIRTUAL COMPETITION: THE PROMISE AND PERILS OF THE
ALGORITHM DRIVEN ECONOMY (2016) (comparing the façade of choice and autonomy on digital platforms to the
Truman Show).
55
For a discussion of the use of online price and behavioral discrimination, see Maurice E. Stucke & Ariel Ezrachi,
How Digital Assistants Can Harm Our Economy, Privacy, and Democracy, 32 B
ERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1239 (2018);
Maurice E. Stucke & Ariel Ezrachi, Alexa et. al., What Are You Doing with My Data?, 5 C
RITICAL ANALYSIS L. 148
(2018).
56
Haley Sweetland Edwards, You’re Addicted to Your Smartphone. This Company Thinks It Can Change That,
T
IME (Apr. 13, 2018, 10:28 AM), http://time.com/5237434/youre-addicted-to-your-smartphone-this-company-
thinks-it-can-change-that.
38
will not be true for all people; some will be taken advantage of under perfect competition if
consumer protection regulations are insufficient. Hence, while this report focuses on the
competition problems created by powerful platforms, related issues raise broader consumer
protection concerns that cannot be solved through greater competition.
ii. The Harms from an Advertising-Supported Business Model
1) Market Power Leads to Markups
Access to high-quality data, scale, and scope has allowed a few large platforms to offer efficient
targeting services for advertising and to dominate the advertising market. Facebook, Google,
and, increasingly, Amazon act as gatekeepers to the online advertising market. The three
platforms provide access to billions of users, as well as a data-rich environment, essential for
modern online advertising. Being in control of the data and the assets—userscreates market
power. That market power generates a profit margin which, for ad-supported platforms, comes
from the sale of advertising. One of the characteristics of the digital advertising environment is
its opacity: major platforms are able to leave bidders and publishers in the dark with respect to
the true success, costs, and profits from placement of advertising. This can be exacerbated when
the platform also supplies buyer or publisher tools and analytics. Opacity is partially a
consequence of market power. Market power can be used to discourage, or even prevent, multi-
homing by buyers. One additional concern is that this opacity may give firms not only the
normal ability to exercise market power in intermediation but also to engage in fraud.
57
Lack of
transparency also undermines buyers’ ability to measure the effectiveness of digital advertising
and therefore to understand its true value relative to price.
58
A report by the French Competition Authority estimated that publishers received 40% of
advertiser sales, with intermediaries collecting the rest.
59
What justifies such a large markup for
intermediaries? Without detailed study we cannot know for sure. However, reasons likely
include the fact that very few platforms can target customers (who may be single-homing) using
detailed and accurate data, so advertisers cannot take advantage of competition. The platforms do
57
See, e.g., Suzanne Vranica & Jack Marshall, Facebook Overestimated Key Video Metric for Two Years, WALL ST.
J. (Sept. 22, 2016), https://www.wsj.com/articles/facebook-overestimated-key-video-metric-for-two-years-
1474586951; Mike Shields, Facebook Says it Found More Miscalculated Metrics, W
ALL ST. J. (Nov. 16, 2016),
https://www.wsj.com/articles/facebook-says-it-found-more-miscalculated-metrics-1479303984; Cyrus Farivar,
Advertisers Allege Facebook Hid the Fact That No One Watches Video Ads, A
RSTECHNICA (Oct. 17, 2018),
https://arstechnica.com/tech-policy/2018/10/advertisers-allege-facebook-hid-the-fact-that-no-one-watches-video-ads
(reporting allegations that Facebook’s “average viewership metrics were not inflated by only 60-80 percent; they
were inflated by some 150-900 percent”).
58
This in turn obscures the size of the platforms’ markup. See SELECT COMMITTEE ON COMMUNICATIONS, HOUSE OF
LORDS, 1ST REPORT OF SESSION 201719, HL PAPER 116, U.K. ADVERTISING IN A DIGITAL AGE 14, § 29 (2018),
https://publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201719/ldselect/ldcomuni/116/116.pdf; David Pidgeon, Where Did the
Money Go? Guardian Buys its Own Ad Inventory, M
EDIA NEWSLINE (Oct. 4, 2016),
https://mediatel.co.uk/newsline/2016/10/04/where-did-the-money-go-guardian-buys-its-own-ad-inventory.
59
FRENCH COMPETITION AUTHORITY REPORT, supra note 1, at 40, § 82.
39
not sell the data to advertisers, but promise to place the ad in front of the requested demographic.
The advertiser lacks transparency or any ability to learn about its customers and potential
customers. Moreover, a platform that operates in the advertising placement business holds the
keys to a second black box through its control of the pricing process.
60
The integration of the
business of running the price-discovery mechanisms as well as tools for each side of the platform
enables opacity, which helps maintain market power. When a platform bundles services such as
advertising placement and return-on-investment analysis with advertiser data such as completed
purchases, it can further enhance its market power.
61
The platform generally never shares the
data with advertisers or publishers, but keeps it to itself, preventing disintermediation by a brand
or publisher, further sustaining its large profit margin.
2) Incentives Created by Markups
Ad-supported platforms’ high markups provide a powerful reason to try and keep users online
for another minute in order to show more ads. These profits push platforms to design their firms
around “engagement”—an obsession with keeping users on their system for as much time, and
with as much attention, as possible.
62
As much of the behavioral literature cited above shows,
advertising-supported digital businesses can use consumer biases to hold people’s attention in
ways that ultimately harm them. Early empirical work has found such effects in social media. In
a recent working paper, Hunt Allcott and colleagues found that Facebook users who were paid to
leave the site for four weeks wound up with higher subjective well-being than similarly situated
people randomly assigned to a group not offered the payment.
63
Users who took the break from
Facebook had a “large and persistent reduction in Facebook use after the experiment,” along
with reduced political polarization and news knowledge.
64
For the platform, engagement serves
two reinforcing purposes. First, the more time a user spends on a platform, the more the platform
knows about her. Second, the longer a user is on the platform, the greater its income from ads
and services. Thus, the more time a user is on the platform, the more ads the platform can sell,
and the more it can charge per ad.
60
For example, Google’s ownership of the ad platforms formerly known as DoubleClick and AdWords. See Todd
Spangler, Google Killing Off DoubleClick, AdWords Names in Rebranding of Ad Products, V
ARIETY (July 27,
2018), https://variety.com/2018/digital/news/google-doubleclick-adwords-rebranding-1202859088.
61
See generally Einer Elhauge, Tying, Bundled Discounts, and the Death of the Single Monopoly Profit Theory, 123
H
ARV. L. REV. 397 (2009).
62
See, e.g., Mark Bergen, YouTube Executives Ignored Warnings, Letting Toxic Videos Run Rampant, BLOOMBERG
(Apr. 2, 2019), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/features/2019-04-02/youtube-executives-ignored-warnings-
letting-toxic-videos-run-rampant (“The company spent years chasing one business goal above others: ‘Engagement,
a measure of the views, time spent and interactions with online videos.”).
63
Hunt Alcott et al., The Welfare Effects of Social Media (NBER Working Paper No. 25514, Apr. 2019),
https://web.stanford.edu/~gentzkow/research/facebook.pdf.
64
Id. at 1.
40
This financial incentive may explain the growing use of tracking and the creation of ecosystems
that are based on the ability to manipulate the user into staying longer on the platform.
65
This
opens the door to exploitative tactics or content as a method of increasing engagement.
Furthermore, a second element to the large margin earned by a platform may be the low cost of
the purchased content that keeps users on the platform. An important question (addressed more
fully by the Media committee) is whether the prices for that content are set competitively. In a
bargaining environment, the market power of the platform may allow it to negotiate a price for
content that is below competitive levels, potentially creating dynamic harm to input providers.
66
The financial incentive created by a large markup can lead to anticompetitive behaviors as well
as exploitative ones. Platforms may seek to reduce interoperability and awareness of outside
options. For example, platforms may exclude certain services or increase friction in accessing
third parties’ services. High search and switching costs are used to “lock in” users and reduce the
ability of competitors to access those users. Platforms may adopt strategies to reduce multi-
homing to obtain more market power over their users. We will return to this theme below.
3) Resulting Quality of Content
As discussed in detail below, the cheapest way to keep users on a platform is to present content
as being more attractive than users thought at the moment when they were ready to leave the
platform, or to make departure more costly in other ways, so that users stay longer. (See a similar
discussion in the Privacy Report.) The platform is essentially degrading the quality of the content
offered in a way that present-biased human beings find engaging. As discussed further below,
content that instantly engages most effectively is content that generates outrage, not necessarily
content that is truthful or thoughtful. Simple strategies such as more advertising minutes per
minute of content also lower quality. Low-quality content represents an increase in the quality-
adjusted price of platform services experienced by consumers.
This business model, and the opacity that accompanies it, makes it difficult for either advertisers
or consumers to realize they are being charged a markup and makes entry into these advertising
markets extremely difficult. Because the advertiser side is where a platform earns its revenue,
this is obviously a key entry barrier. The question of how an enforcer or regulator might enable
entrants to overcome this barrier to entry is an important part of the discussion in Section III.B of
the report.
65
See Maurice E. Stucke & Ariel Ezrachi, The Subtle Ways Your Digital Assistant Might Manipulate You, WIRED
(Nov. 29, 2016, 8:00 AM), https://www.wired.com/2016/11/subtle-ways-digital-assistant-might-manipulate.
66
See Maurice E. Stucke & Ariel Ezrachi, Looking Up in the Data-Driven Economy, COMPETITION POLY INTL
(May 15, 2017), https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/looking-up-in-the-data-driven-economy.
41
4) Welfare and Efficiency
When analyzing the impact of online advertising and the behaviors it creates, one should keep in
mind that antitrust aims to promote effective competition for the benefit of consumers.
Competition authorities tend to treat advertisers as any other customers of a service. The premise
is that market power in advertising channels impedes the ability of brands to reach consumers
and inform them about their products. Such a treatment of the welfare from advertising relies on
the implicit view that i) the role of advertising is solely to inform consumers; and ii) competition
in the advertising market leads to efficiency. The economic literature tells us that both
assumptions are questionable, as does observation of digital markets.
67
In competition policy,
when assessing the impact of a decision or a regulation involving advertising, it is important to
focus on the final impact on consumers and market efficiency rather than on the advertisers
surplus.
On the one hand, targeted advertising to wise and well-informed consumers is welfare-improving
insofar as it allows advertisers to send the right information to the right people, improving their
choices and fostering competition among suppliers. On the other hand, in the modern economy
this simple model becomes more complex because of the cost to the consumer, namely loss of
privacy. There is an open empirical question as to whether the tradeoff is worthwhile to
consumers.
68
We discuss the problem of measuring welfare in a setting where consumers are
manipulated below.
iii. Online Exploitation and Addiction
1) Human Reward Systems
Digital platforms’ manipulation of their users—in part designed to get users addictedis getting
a considerable amount of attention from the public. These actions lower the quality of a platform
and harm users.
As discussed above, some platforms have deliberately incorporated features that feed human
“reward” centers into their products to induce users to give more and more of their time—and
datato the platform. These tools are designed for scale—they become even more valuable the
more traffic they carry and the more users they garner—and hence the competition among
producers has been described as a competition for eyeballs.
69
Because the digital tools and
67
See, e.g., Anderson, S. P., Waldfogel, J., & Stromberg, D. (Eds.). Handbook of Media Economics, vol. 1A (2016).
Elsevier; Goldfarb, A., & Tucker, C. Digital economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 57(1), 3-43 (2019).
68
See, e.g., Elizabeth Aguirre et al., Unraveling the Personalization Paradox: The Effect of Information Collection
and Trust-Building Strategies on Online Advertisement Effectiveness, 91 J.
RETAILING 34 (2015); Justin P. Johnson,
Targeted Advertising and Advertising Avoidance, 44 R
AND J. ECON. 128 (2013).
69
See, e.g., Doni Bloomfield, High-Speed Ad Traders Profit by Arbitraging Your Eyeballs, BLOOMBERG (Nov. 7,
2014), https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-11-07/high-speed-ad-traders-profit-by-arbitraging-your-
eyeballs.
42
networks have been designed for use at scale, and because there is relatively little cost and
considerable benefit associated with adding more users, producers want as much user
engagement as they can get. The creators of digital products have benefited from social science
and neuroscience findings that concern, for example, how certain colors or mechanics can feed a
user’s dopamine, much as nicotine does.
70
The Center for Humane Technology, which calls the
problem the “hijacking of our society,” describes the issues as follows:
Facebook, Twitter, Instagram, and Google have produced amazing products that have
benefited the world enormously. But these companies are also caught in a zero-sum race
for our finite attention, which they need to make money. Constantly forced to outperform
their competitors, they must use increasingly persuasive techniques to keep us glued.
They point AI-driven news feeds, content, and notifications at our minds, continually
learning how to hook us more deeply—from our own behavior.
71
This business model is based on acquiring a large volume of data to generate income, and it has
led to unprecedented investment in addiction—ensuring continuing use of the interface. From
diaper apps,
72
to rewarded ads (in which viewers are given in-app rewards, such as another “life”
in a video game, in return for watching an ad)
73
internet firms harness their knowledge of
second-to-second individual responses alongside social science learnings about human biases for
maximum attention.
74
Researchers do not yet know the full extent of the harm (or potential
harm) that may come from this sort of addiction and manipulation, but they are now actively
engaged in relevant research.
75
What is known is that a business that depends on users staying
online to watch ads and have their preferences harvested will focus its resources on keeping
70
See Edwards, supra note 56.
71
Ctr. for Humane Tech., Our Society is Being Hijacked by Technology, HUMANE TECH (2018),
http://humanetech.com/problem.
72
Edwards, supra note 56.
73
Rewarded Ads: A Win for Users, Developers, and Advertisers, GOOGLE ADMOB (2018),
https://admob.google.com/home/resources/rewarded-ads-win-for-everyone.
74
The video app TikTok may have taken this approach to its logical conclusion. See John Herrman, How TikTok is
Rewriting the World, N.Y.
TIMES (Mar. 10, 2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/03/10/style/what-is-tik-tok.html
(“TikTok assertively answers anyone’s what should I watch with a flood . . . [the app] has stepped over the midpoint
between the familiar self-directed feed and an experience based first on algorithmic observation and inference. . . .
It’s an algorithmic feed based on videos you’ve interacted with, or even just watched. It never runs out of material. It
is not, unless you train it to be, full of people you know, or things you’ve explicitly told it you want to see. It’s full
of things that you seem to have demonstrated you want to watch, no matter what you actually say you want to
watch.”).
75
See, e.g., Daria J. Kuss et al., Problematic Mobile Phone Use and Addiction Across Generations: The Roles of
Psychopathological Symptoms and Smartphone Use, 3 J.
TECH. BEHAVIORAL SCI. 141 (2018); José De-Sola
Gutiérrez et al., Cell-Phone Addiction: A Review, 7 F
RONTIERS PSYCHIATRY 175 (2016) (noting “a consensus about
the existence of cell-phone addiction, but the delimitation and criteria used by various researchers vary”). The field
is still nascent and there is no consensus that internet addiction exists or is a distinct psychological condition. See
Francesca C. Ryding & Linda K. Kaye, “Internet Addiction”: A Conceptual Minefield, 16 I
NT. J. MENTAL HEALTH
& ADDICTION 225 (2018) (criticizing the cavalier use of the term “internet addiction” without a firmer grasp of the
problem); Kristyn Zajac et al., Treatments for Internet Gaming Disorder and Internet Addiction: A Systematic
Review, 31 P
SYCH. ADDICTIVE BEHAVIORS 979 (2017).
43
users online—for example, with intelligent and flexible algorithms.
76
The algorithm will learn
from, and respond to, these basic human preferences, thereby delivering—perhaps along with
good content—a large quantity of low-quality content.
77
2) Examples
There are many examples of exploitation of consumers who have sunk costs in a platform and
may not be fully informed. For example, app designers have enticed children into playing free
games that are built around in-app purchases, leading children to make large purchases without
parental knowledge or permission. The U.K.’s consumer protection agency, the Office of Fair
Trading, found that such purchases could be pricey: “A My Little Pony game, for example,
offer[ed] users a virtual ‘mountain of gems’ for a real-life £69.99.”
78
Regulators around the
world have cracked down to force companies to refund large payments that children make on
their parents’ phones.
79
More disturbing examples of low-quality content are YouTube
recommended videos that lead the viewer towards false or dangerous content.
80
Prior to having
these patterns made public and criticized, a Google search about the earth’s geology would lead
to a chain of recommendations that resulted in “flat earth” content;
81
YouTube would offer
76
Beginning in 2014, Twitter followed Facebook in centering around algorithm-selected content rather than simply
displaying tweets from accounts a user chooses to follow in reverse chronological order. See Will Oremus, Twitter’s
New Order, S
LATE (Mar. 5, 2017),
http://www.slate.com/articles/technology/cover_story/2017/03/twitter_s_timeline_algorithm_and_its_effect_on_us_
explained.html.
77
See Paul Lewis, ‘Fiction is Outperforming Reality’: How YouTube’s Algorithm Distorts Truth, GUARDIAN (Feb.
2, 2018), https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2018/feb/02/how-youtubes-algorithm-distorts-truth; Paul Lewis
& Erin McCormick, How an Ex-YouTube Insider Investigated its Secret Algorithm, G
UARDIAN (Feb. 2, 2018),
https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2018/feb/02/youtube-algorithm-election-clinton-trump-guillaume-chaslot;
see also Aim of the Project, A
LGOTRANSPARENCY,
https://algotransparency.org/methodology.html?candidat=Francois%20Fillon&file=ytrecos-presidentielle-2017-06-
10.
78
Hilary Osborne, OFT Warns Free Online Games Pressure Children Into In-app Purchases, GUARDIAN (Sept. 26,
2013), https://www.theguardian.com/money/2013/sep/26/free-online-games-children-apps.
79
See Press Release, U.K. Competition & Markets Authority, CMA Refers 3 Games to the ASA (June 4, 2015),
https://www.gov.uk/government/news/cma-refers-three-childrens-online-games-to-the-asa; Press Release, Fed.
Trade Comm’ n, Apple Inc. Will Provide Full Consumer Refunds of At Least $32.5 Million to Settle FTC
Complaint It Charged for Kids’ In-App Purchases Without Parental Consent (Jan. 15, 2015),
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2014/01/apple-inc-will-provide-full-consumer-refunds-least-325-
million; Press Release, Euro. Union, In-app Purchases: Joint Action by the European Commission and Member
States is Leading to Better Protection for Consumers in Online Games (July 18, 2014), http://europa.eu/rapid/press-
release_IP-14-847_en.htm.
80
See Bergen, supra note 62.
81
See Casey Newton, How YouTube Helps Flat-Earthers Organize, VERGE (Feb. 20, 2019),
https://www.theverge.com/interface/2019/2/20/18232524/youtube-flat-earth-recommendation-algorithm-conspiracy;
Press Release, Google, Continuing Our Work to Improve Recommendations on YouTube (Jan. 25, 2019) (noting
that the company was planning to “begin reducing recommendations of borderline content and content that could
misinform users in harmful wayssuch as videos promoting a phony miracle cure for a serious illness, claiming the
earth is flat, or making blatantly false claims about historic events like 9/11”); see also Kevin Roose, YouTube
Unleashed a Conspiracy Theory Boom. Can it Be Contained?, N.Y.
TIMES (Feb. 19, 2019),
https://www.nytimes.com/2019/02/19/technology/youtube-conspiracy-stars.html.
44
teenage girls interested in diets videos about how to get anorexia, and so forth.
82
It is important
to realize that this content is not chosen by human curators at the platform. Rather, the algorithm
learns what content people will click on, and what content will cause them to stay on the
platform longer, through many millions of small experiments; that is the content that is suggested
and viewed. Exploitation and addiction caused by the optimization of the platform is a harm to
consumers because they are likely watching lower-quality content than they would choose if they
were fully informed in advance about how the content is chosen, or perhaps if they had
alternative platforms to choose among.
iv. Privacy
Another worry is that the privacy of consumers on digital platforms is violated; this too is a
decline in the quality of the product. For example, Facebook recently announced that it will
merge the infrastructures of Facebook Messenger, WhatsApp, and Instagram. As the New York
Times noted, “[t]he integration plan raises privacy questions because of how users’ data may be
shared between services. WhatsApp historically required only a phone number when new users
signed up. By contrast, Facebook and Facebook Messenger ask users to provide their true
identities. Matching Facebook and Instagram users to their WhatsApp handles could harm those
who prefer to keep their use of each app separate.”
83
Germany’s competition regulator responded
to this announcement by prohibiting Facebook from combining data from different sources (such
as WhatsApp or Instagram) with data from Facebook.com without a user’s explicit and voluntary
consent.
84
Facebook’s eagerness to get third-party apps connected to its network has led to mass
data leaks, exposing sensitive information from hundreds of millions of people.
85
And Facebook
is hardly alone.
86
82
See Nicholas Tompson, When Tech Knows You Better Than You Know Yourself, WIRED (Oct. 4, 2018),
https://www.wired.com/story/artificial-intelligence-yuval-noah-harari-tristan-harris/ (reporting Tristan Harris, head
of the Center for Humane Technology, arguing that “[t]he problem is [YouTube] doesn't actually care about what
you want, it just cares about what will keep you next on the screen. The thing that works best at keeping a teenage
girl watching a dieting video on YouTube the longest is to say here's an anorexia video”).
83
Mike Isaac, Zuckerberg Plans to Integrate WhatsApp, Instagram and Facebook Messenger, N.Y. TIMES (Jan. 25,
2019), https://www.nytimes.com/2019/01/25/technology/facebook-instagram-whatsapp-messenger.html.
84
See Bundeskartellamt, supra note 37.
85
See, e.g., Data on 540 Million Facebook Users Exposed, BBC (Apr. 4, 2019),
https://www.bbc.com/news/technology-47812470; Millions of Facebook Passwords Exposed Internally, BBC (Mar.
21, 2019), https://www.bbc.com/news/technology-47653656.
86
See, e.g., Douglas MacMillan & Robert McMillan, Google Exposed User Data, Feared Repercussions of
Disclosing to Public, W
ALL ST. J. (Oct. 8, 2018), https://www.wsj.com/articles/google-exposed-user-data-feared-
repercussions-of-disclosing-to-public-1539017194; Chaim Gartenberg, Twitter Advising All 330 Million Users to
Change Passwords After Bug Exposed Them in Plain Text, V
ERGE (May 3, 2018),
https://www.theverge.com/2018/5/3/17316684/twitter-password-bug-security-flaw-exposed-change-now.
45
b. The Assessment Problem
i. Measuring Consumer Welfare in a Behavioral World
Each of these issues results in fundamental difficulties in applying standard antitrust analysis
which is related to the assessment of the welfare effects of various practices or of a merger—to
digital markets. Adequate measures of volume, quality, and consumer surplus may be difficult to
obtain. The number of users choosing a certain option may not reflect their true preferences if the
platform can make that choice a default that is difficult to see or to change. The number of clicks
on ads may not correlate with greater welfare if higher volume of clicks is obtained by exploiting
lack of self-control and addictive behaviors.
Given the prevalence of behavioral effects in the digital economy, the measurement of consumer
welfare must be carried out very carefully. As we have mentioned, behavioral economics is now
a well-established discipline that can help sort different online behaviors and business practices.
Incorporating this knowledge into the legal practice’s toolbox may help develop better measures
of output and quality.
87
We caution, however, that the legal structure of US antitrust law is not
well set up to accommodate this complexity as it opens the door for judges to weigh all manner
of social concerns as well as traditional economic effects. We see two approaches that might be
more fruitful. First, the fastest route to more accurate measures of welfare might well be for a
digital regulator to limit the business models that serve harmful content, the way regulators limit
the harm from mortgages by restricting debt to income ratios, the harm from prescription drugs
by requiring access through a physician, and the harm from automobiles by requiring airbags and
crash tests, to name a few examples. If platforms had little or no incentive to deliver harmful
content to consumers, the standard consumer welfare toolkit would be more accurate in this
market. Second, harmful content is also, from the viewpoint of the consumer’s long run or ex
ante self, low-quality content. Analytical paradigms in antitrust analysis commonly deal with low
quality and quality-adjusted prices, and could incorporate the role of exploitative content in this
way.
Another reason to be pessimistic about measuring traditional surplus concepts is related to the
barter nature of the exchange: Users barter attention and personal data for services. With a “free
service, consumers are paying for any expansion of activity with their attention to content. When
facing a zero-money price, and when quality is difficult to observe, consumers are not receiving
salient signals about the social value of their consumption because the price they believe they
face does not reflect the economics of the transaction, and they are ignorant of those numbers.
87
For a view of the role behavioral economics can play in legal practice, see THE OXFORD HANDBOOK OF
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS AND THE LAW (Eyal Zamir & Doron Teichman eds., 2014).
46
ii. Assessing the Social Welfare of Advertising
Behavioral economics also calls for careful use of standard economic surplus measures when
applied to the supply of advertising. Unlike supply of goods, higher value of advertising need not
imply higher social value. As discussed above, when advertising efficacy relies on psychological
nudges that bring people into consumption they would consciously avoid otherwise, more
advertising may well mean less consumer welfare.
Moreover, while price competition directly benefits consumers, competition through persuasive
advertising may waste resources.
88
To see this point, consider the following example: Two firms
share the market equally without advertising. If one then uses advertising and shifts the demand
toward that firm (perhaps by some psychological effect), it will then have a larger share of the
market. However, if both firms decide to advertise, they will continue to share the market
equally. If the advertising cost is not too large, both firms will advertise in order to preserve their
market share. Therefore, despite advertising spending, the equilibrium sales and consumption are
the same as without advertising. Here, allowing for advertising only induces wasteful spending,
which in our setting is captured by the platform as profit. This is an extreme example, but it
highlights that a higher volume of advertisingand greater platform profitsmay not indicate
an increase in social welfare in the same way we normally think a higher output of, for example,
shoes, would indicate.
c. Harms to Investment and Innovation
i. Rents
Successful platform-style strategies pre-date the internet. For example, the key to Microsoft’s
business was the orchestration of ecosystem-wide innovation—the personal computer industry—
to benefit its own core offering as well as complements provided by third-party partners.
89
The
strategy we highlight in this section of the report is a successful platform’s choice of how much
rent to expropriate from these complementors. For example, Microsoft turned PC hardware—an
essential complement to an operating system—into a commodity business with the main
exception of the microprocessor made by Intel. However, PC applications software—again an
88
Although subtler, the same point has been shown to hold in the economic literature about informative advertising
that conveys useful information about products such as existence, location, and other product characteristics. See
Kyle Bagwell, The Economic Analysis of Advertising, in 3 H
ANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION
(Mark Armstrong & Robert Porter eds., 2007), https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-448X(06)03028-7; Simon P.
Anderson & Régis Renault, Advertising Content, 96 A
MER. ECON. REV. 93 (2006). In this case advertising brings
real value to consumers. But competition to steer consumers from other suppliers and/or to preserve market share
may still lead to excessive spending on advertising.
89
See ANNABELLE GAWER & MICHAEL A. CUSUMANO, PLATFORM LEADERSHIP: HOW INTEL, MICROSOFT, AND
CISCO DRIVE INDUSTRY INNOVATION (2002) (detailing the characteristics of these types of platforms).
47
essential complement to the OSremained (in part) an area where other firms could enter,
compete, and earn profit.
The level of market power attached to a successful platform is so high that it often gives the
platform owner the ability to expropriate almost the entire surplus available on its platform. And
the ability to add that surplus to its existing core profit is the incentive to do so. For example,
Microsoft’s actions to favor Word over WordPerfect expropriated surplus from an existing
software complement to its operating system. Importantly, in this example, WordPerfect was not
a potential entrant into, or substitute for, a PC operating system, so there was not an exclusionary
theme. The distinction between complementors that could disintermediate the platform and are
therefore potential rivals, and those that cannot is critical for the antitrust analysis below. When
the platform owner takes steps to disadvantage complementors who have no market power, the
complementors may resist by using non-market (political and legal) strategies. Such
complainants were part of the antitrust cases against Microsoft. We see this response to current
platforms by firms in Europe today.
Chamath Palihapitiya, a venture capitalist, has quoted Bill Gates as arguing that a platform exists
whenever “the economic value of everybody that uses it exceeds the value of the company that
creates it.”
90
In that world, complementors earn rents. By contrast, Ben Thompson, a tech
journalist, argues that Facebook and Google are what he calls aggregators—firms that
completely control the relationship between suppliers and users.
91
His point is that this control
allows the aggregator to exercise market power over one side of the platform, control access by
the other side, and extract all the rents. This emphasis on the creation of complementor rents and
their distribution or expropriation is a theme that runs through this Report.
When and how a platform appropriates the rents of its complementors varies and may engender
different responses from complementors. At root, the reason the complementor is there in the
first place is because the platform originally needed content to attract consumers, so it invited the
complementors onto the platform. Businesses selling widgets on ecommerce sites, games on
social media, and mapping apps on handsets, are all examples of complements that were critical
to successfully launching a platform. The complementors make these investments thinking they
will obtain a return, and that expected return leads to efficient levels of investment. If
investments were made knowing that the returns would be zero, there might well be dynamic
harm because the platform would not be able to get off the ground. (Or alternatively, the owner
of the platform would have to vertically integrate into many applications and provide them
90
Interview by Semile Shah with Chamath Palihapitiya, CEO, Social Capital (Sept. 16, 2015),
http://haystack.vc/2015/09/17/transcript-chamath-at-strictlyvcs-insider-series.
91
Ben Thompson, Tech’s Two Philosophies, STRATECHERY (May 9, 2018), https://stratechery.com/2018/techs-two-
philosophies (contrasting platforms, such as Microsoft and Apple, which “need 3rd parties to make them useful and
build their moat through the creation of ecosystems,” with aggregators, such as Facebook and Google, which “attract
end users by virtue of their inherent usefulness and, over time, leave suppliers no choice but to follow the
aggregators’ dictates if they wish to reach end users”).
48
itself.) A significant source of discontent today seems to come from complementors who
invested believing that they could capture surplus with a good product and who are later
expropriated by the platform. A second discontented group are the complementors that existed in
the brick and mortar world and now have no choice but to use a dominant platform, so they have
no bargaining power despite providing valuable products or services.
If the expropriation is accomplished using a tool that is anticompetitive, it may violate
competition laws. In the United States, this antitrust violation can be established when the
complementor may be able to disintermediate the platform and is therefore a potential rival, for
example, Netscape and Windows.
92
If such a move is not a violation of competition law but
violates the expectations of market participants, it may be viewed as unfair. On the other hand, if
the platform has significantly improved quality or engaged in innovation, market participants
may think the platform fairly earned those rents.
Digital platforms have a variety of rent-extraction strategies that seem to be loosely related to the
social scrutiny they are receiving.
93
For example, the news industry had no choice but to use
Facebook. But Facebook has been reluctant to share any of its profits with news companies—and
its market power has meant it hasn’t had to.
94
Interestingly, when content providers have market
power, the platform cannot always extract rents, even when it has a high market share. Take the
hypothetical case of a fragmented travel platform industry in a geography where the airline
market is concentrated. In that setting airlines could disintermediate a travel site by withholding
their participation in the site, or by favoring their own sales channels. The equilibrium division
of platform rents in this case will favor the powerful content providers, the airlines, rather than
the platforms.
95
Market participants observe that Facebook has slowly commoditized most
companies which supply attention to its users—from news and content markets to games and
apps, companies’ profits deriving from Facebook have slowly diminished as Facebook
appropriated most of the gains.
96
These trends may be part of the reason there is growing
attention to Facebook’s business model today.
92
The antitrust theories of harm that cover this case are discussed below.
93
See, e.g., Josh Dzieza, Prime and Punishment: Dirty Dealing in the $175 Billion Amazon Marketplace, VERGE
(Dec. 19, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/12/19/18140799/amazon-marketplace-scams-seller-court-appeal-
reinstatement (discussing the fear Amazon sellers have of the firm and its ability to shut them down with little or no
explanation); Izabella Kaminska, Amazon (sub)Prime?, F
IN. TIMES (Mar. 20, 2019),
https://ftalphaville.ft.com/2019/03/20/1553085361000/Amazon--sub-Prime-.
94
See Ben Thompson, The Buzzfeed Lesson, STRATECHERY (Jan. 28, 2019), https://stratechery.com/2019/the-
buzzfeed-lesson (“[C]ontent suppliers are absolutely commoditized: Facebook doesn’t need to do anything to keep
them on the platform, because where else will they go? Might as well keep the money for itself.”).
95
For a related setting, see Fiona Scott Morton et al., Benefits of Preserving Consumers’ Ability to Compare Airline
Fares, (unpublished manuscript, 2015) (on file with authors).
96
See, e.g., Thompson, supra note 94; Pete Brown, More Than Half of Facebook Instant Articles Partners Have
Abandoned It, C
OLUM. J. REV. (Feb. 2, 2018), https://www.cjr.org/tow_center/are-facebook-instant-articles-worth-
it.php; Harrison Weber, Facebook Kicked Zynga to the Curb, Publishers Are Next, V
ENTUREBEAT (June 30, 2016),
https://venturebeat.com/2016/06/30/facebook-kicked-zynga-to-the-curb-publishers-are-next.
49
Today’s prominent tech companies most likely learned from older tech businesses that those
older businesses had “lost,” or shared, a too-high percentage of profits with their ecosystems.
While older businesses were continually confronted with questions about what to own versus
what to cede to partners on their platform, without today’s technological advancements
(including advanced data analytics and greater computational power), older platforms were not
as swift and flexible in capturing value as current digital platforms can be. The increased scale
and scope of control has provided modern digital platform owners with increased power over
their ecosystems. Today’s platforms understand that they can obtain higher margins if they either
make all of the necessary complements themselves or position themselves as a mandatory
bottleneck between partners and customers—leading to many platforms taking a significant
commission on sales on their platform or extracting value through barter of information. In
particular, today’s digital platforms are very careful to maintain complete control over the user
relationship so that they do not face any threat of disintermediation. These choices can be used to
reduce the possibility of successful entry by an innovator in the platform’s space. The next
section turns to this problem of entry.
d. Harm to Entry, Including Disintermediation
i. The Practical Consequence of Entry Barriers
When evaluating entry as the main source of competition against a platform, as discussed above,
the entrant has a significant disadvantage relative to the platform. Venture capitalist investors
will often evaluate a startup based on its ability to either access or build enough data swiftly
enough, all with the aim of reaching enough insights to take advantage of all the forces discussed
above. In other words, a new entrant starved of data, quantitatively and qualitatively speaking,
relative to a tech giant, is at a significant competitive disadvantage, and investors will be unlikely
to invest if they view that data deficit as insurmountable. Although it can be attractive for a VC
to invest in a firm that may be acquired by Facebook, Google, or Amazon, the road to a
successful acquisition is fraught with danger, most notably the ability of any of these three giants
to replicate a specific feature, functionality, or business model should other considerations such
as intellectual property rights, team quality, defensibility, or time to market not weigh against
such copycat strategy. Additionally, investors do not always fare well in these acquisitions.
97
ii. Incumbent Incentive to Leverage Entry Barriers
There is growing evidence that conglomerate digital platforms are in an advantaged position to
stop or block entry by more focused rivals when compared to traditional businesses. Companies
like Alphabet, Amazon, and Facebook operate in multiple business verticals (for example, mail,
97
See, e.g., Rachel Kraus, Amazon Bought Eero for $97 Million and Employees Still Got Screwed, MASHABLE (Apr.
5, 2019), https://mashable.com/article/amazon-eero-wifi-router-sale/#HN0veV33jPqc (“Ultimately, thanks to a ‘last
in, first out’ philosophy, Eero’s Series D investors, led by Qualcomm, will recoup 84 percent of their investments.
The seed round and Series A-C investors will all get back 31 cents on the dollar.”).
50
maps, and search), collecting different dimensions of data on a consumer (for example, identity,
location, and purchase intent) which give faster intelligence on competitive threats and new
chinks in the platform’s competitive armor. These companies can then derive superior insights
into what firms they should block, which they should buy, and how they should grow
strategically. This gives the platform an advantage over a rival entrant considering the same set
of opportunities, and increases their abilities to exclude such rivals. A rival platform with similar
economies of scope, data insights, and installed base may be a more formidable entrant.
If large digital platforms have both the incentive and ability to purchase and block entrants that
compete with them, or might compete in the future, the question is whether they have done so.
The evidence that platforms have bought a series of potential competitors in recent years is
anecdotal but fairly robust.
98
For example, many observers believe that Instagram and WhatsApp
might well have been serious competitors for Facebook.
99
The evidence that platforms have
blocked potential entrants is likewise anecdotal
100
and was used in the Android and AdSense
cases the European Commission has brought against Google.
101
More formal research in this
area is essential.
iii. Disintermediation and Foreclosure of Potential Platform
Entrants
In addition to de novo entry, platforms fear disintermediation by a partner. If a platform’s partner
is able to directly access and serve the platform’s customers, it can overtake the platform.
Disintermediation can also occur through commoditizing services so that one side (normally the
end consumer) is willing to substitute away from the platformleading to a loss of profits.
The threat of disintermediation has important implications for the analysis of market entry and
foreclosure. Modern platforms have an incentive to regularly thwart companies that compete with
them for user demand. A platform that has total control of demand can steer customers to content
and complements it owns rather than to those provided by independent firms that might challenge
its market power. And because of potential harm to competition and complements, US regulators
have often been tasked with preventing discrimination, foreclosure, and similar strategies in
specific industries.
102
Without a great deal of insight into the technology and the strategy of the
platform, foreclosure will be difficult to observe by outsiders. Technological tools such as mobile
hardware technologies, advances in computing power, communications technologies, application
98
See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 49, tbl.1A.
99
Tim Wu, The Case for Breaking Up Facebook and Instagram, WASH. POST (Sept. 28, 2018),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2018/09/28/case-breaking-up-facebook-instagram.
100
American Tech Giants Are Making Life Tough for Startups, ECONOMIST (June 2, 2018),
https://www.economist.com/business/2018/06/02/american-tech-giants-are-making-life-tough-for-startups.
101
Press Release, Eur. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google €1.49 Billion for Abusive Practices in Online
Advertising (Mar. 20, 2019), http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-19-1770_en.htm.
102
See Lina Khan, The Separation of Platforms and Commerce, 119 COLUM. L. R. (forthcoming 2019),
https://papers.ssrn.com/id=3180174.
51
programming interfaces (API), cloud computing technologies, and data analytics enable a strategy
of keeping the attractive content from establishing a relationship with the user and thereby possibly
entering as a competitor. Platforms have bluntly moved to prevent disintermediation and have
engaged in foreclosure to block potential rivals. For example, Facebook acted to suppress the
growth video-capture-and-sharing app Vine when Vine attempted to link its users to their
Facebook friends.
103
Facebook CEO Mark Zuckerberg personally approved the decision to prevent
Vine users from finding friends on the app via Facebook.
104
Exclusive contracts and loyalty contracts can also be used to achieve exclusion. For example, a
long-term contract that requires an advertiser not to use an entrant can foreclose demand from
that entrant, leading to exit. An exclusive contract with a global reach can prevent an able niche
competitor from growing larger and obtaining economies of scale. Bundling of services by the
incumbent platform can be designed to exclude entry or foreclose existing rivals. Contracts
between platforms and advertisers that allow for individual negotiation can protect an incumbent
from losing individual targeted sales to an entrant without requiring the incumbent to lower its
prices across the board. An incumbent platform with market power will often have the incentive
and ability to undertake these strategies and thereby preserve its profit.
iv. Foreclosure of Complements to Capture Rents
One critical place to control the relationship is platform access. Amazon and Facebook regularly
make decisions over which app or vendor is able to sell or is denied access to their stores and
customers. Platforms often have a financial incentive to steer customers to particularly profitable
products and can use the power of defaults and ordering to accomplish that effectively. Vendors
operate in a risky environment where the platform’s whims can determine its future as much or
more than consumer satisfaction. If it chooses, a platform can steer demand elsewhere and the
vendor loses access to its customers—because these customers are another company’s users who
single-home and buy from the default choice at the top of the page. Provided the consumer
continues to find the totality of the platform experience positive, this bargaining power allows
the platform to dictate business terms. The Vestager Report describes the setting clearly:
Other platforms impose rules and institutions that reach beyond the pure matching
services and shape the functioning of the marketplace and, potentially, the relationship
between the various platform sides, e.g. by regulating access to and exclusion from the
platform, by regulating the way in which sellers can present their offers, the data and
APIs they can access, setting up grading systems, regulating access to information that is
generated on the platform, imposing minimum standards for delivery and return policies,
103
See Adi Robertson, Mark Zuckerberg Personally Approved Cutting Off Vine’s Friend-finding Feature, VERGE
(Dec. 18, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/12/5/18127202/mark-zuckerberg-facebook-vine-friends-api-block-
parliament-documents.
104
See id. Several years after buying Vine, Twitter shut it down. See Casey Newton, Why Vine Died, VERGE (Oct. 28,
2016), https://www.theverge.com/2016/10/28/13456208/why-vine-died-twitter-shutdown.
52
providing for model contracts, imposing price controls and MFN clauses, etc. Such rule-
setting and “market design” determine the way in which competition takes place.
105
The way competition takes place determines the level of profit achieved by the platform and
each complement. In and of itself, a platform setting the terms of trade, quality levels, services,
and so on may not be problematic if the purpose of the change is to “grow the pie” in a way that
complementors view as fair (i.e., not involving expropriation). For example, Amazon, Facebook,
or Google know in real time which products are sold to whom, at what price, and which
packaging or incentives work, which may drive their rules. However, if these rules become
opaque and uncertain or the insights gleaned from an app or vendor are biased or used against it
in an asymmetrical manner, then the rule changes may not be about increasing everyone’s
revenue, but about moving a larger share to the platform.
Merchants or vendors can find themselves banned, demoted in search results, or required to bear
higher costs without the ability to move to a competing platform because either there is none or
because the customers single-home, will not depart the platform because of the loss of one
vendor, and cannot be reached elsewhere. The EC’s Android case describes the disadvantage
faced by independent apps that compete with the Google apps that are included in the mandatory
bundle.
106
Twitter has vertically integrated into video streaming by foreclosing the rival service
Meerkat.
107
Likewise, by selling logistics services to many of its sellers, Amazon gains an
advantage when it wishes to launch a store brand. It can analyze the data from its rivals to
develop an entry plan against those sellers. It is important to measure whether, and how much,
quality increases with these strategies.
It is not clear what profits such complementors expected or achieved from the platform
relationship, nor if there was significant relationship-specific investment required. Vendors may
be less likely to enter the market at all, or to innovate, if they know they must distribute through
a particular platform and their most successful products will be quickly copied. Businesses that
could grow on a platform and increase the platform’s attractiveness to consumers will be
unwilling to invest if their profits are not secure, and this may be a source of dynamic
inefficiency. However, platforms have an incentive to attract good complements in order to
105
EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 60.
106
The recent Spotify complaint against Apple in Europe is another example. See James Vincent, Spotify Files
Antitrust Complaint Over ‘Apple Tax, V
ERGE (Mar. 13, 2019),
https://www.theverge.com/2019/3/13/18263453/spotify-apple-app-store-antitrust-complaint-ec-30-percent-cut-
unfair.
107
See Feng Zhu, Friends or Foes? Examining Platform Owners’ Entry Into Complementors’ Spaces, 28 J. ECON. &
MGMT. STRAT. 23, 23 (2018) (“Meerkat, a mobile app that enabled Twitter users to broadcast live video streaming
to their followers, vanished after Twitter acquired its competitor Periscope and cut off Meerkat’s access to Twitter’s
social graph.”); see also Chris Welch, Tumblr ‘Truly Disappointed by Twitter’s Decision’ to Block Friend-Finding
On the Blogging Service, V
ERGE (Aug. 22, 2012), https://www.theverge.com/2012/8/22/3261270/tumblr-removes-
twitter-find-people-you-know. Twitter acquired Periscope, a competing startup, and then decided to shut out
Meerkat. On October 2016, Meerkat was shut down. Currently, Periscope is fully integrated with the Twitter
platform and claims 1.9 million daily users (last updated and released info as of 2017).
53
attract users. This incentive limits the platform’s desire to expropriate complementor rents under
some circumstances.
e. Harm to Innovation
i. Competition Promotes Innovation
There is significant theoretical and empirical research that concludes that anticompetitive
creation or maintenance of market power will cause a reduction in the pace of innovation.
108
This result is intuitive in the sense that firms “run faster” when they face competitors; competing
firms will try to offer a better product on any dimension consumers care about, including
innovation. Engaging in successful innovation is certainly both feasible and common for a large
platform with its enormous collection of data and other assets. These companies routinely spend
large sums on R&D, launch new products and services, and are more able than other competitors
to derive superior insights into how they should innovate based on the data collected from
aggregating demand and advances in machine learning and advanced data analytics. However,
the relevant counterfactual is whether the pace of innovation would be faster if platforms faced
more robust competition.
ii. Entry Barriers and Innovation
The lessening or blocking of innovative entry is of particular concern given its value. A VC will
usually be wary of outright investing in an innovative startup that will implicitly or explicitly
compete head-on with a tech giant. Given the tech incumbents’ ability to block or foreclose a
threatening entrant, the chance of successful entry is tiny. VCs would rather invest in businesses
that are creating new categories or solving common technical issues. Take Google’s search
engine as an example. To our knowledge there is only one search engine that has reached a
successful market size as a standalone business: Duck Duck Go. Google search is the dominant
firm in this category with high entry barriers; despite the enormous size of this market, VC
investors apparently do not want to fund an entrant. By contrast, VCs are attracted to startup
teams that solve a specific issue for Google (and have a chance of buyout) as opposed to funding
a team that wants to compete head to head. This dynamic leads to a self-fulfilling prophecy.
Reduced VC investment due to the inability to enter successfully in fact causes less entry; and
less investment also causes less differentiated innovation in the sector. This can be seen
increasingly by evidence of platform acquisitions.
109
Despite very high and stable profit margins,
markets like social media and search have faced little entry.
108
For a comprehensive survey of the innovation literature, see the literature summarized in Giulio Federico, Fiona
Scott Morton & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust and Innovation: Welcoming and Protecting Disruption (NBER Innovation
Policy and the Economy, Working Paper, 2019) (on file with authors).
109
The number of potential competitors purchased by the tech giants is large. For example, Amazon has purchased
Zappos, Fabric, CDNow, Quorus, Audible, Goodreads, and Quisdi; Facebook has acquired WhatsApp, Instagram,
54
As discussed above, large tech platforms can combine enormous financial resources with data
resources. Digital platforms have an ability to produce free cash flows at a speed and level that is
entirely new because of the combination of almost zero marginal cost, instant distribution, and
global reach. This advantage creates both the incentive and the ability for the digital platform to
outspend, to out-invest, or to acquire incumbents or new competitors. Incumbents have the
incentive and ability to stand in the way of possibly disruptive innovation. With deep pockets,
they can purchase possible future disruptors in order to align the path of innovation with their
strategies or otherwise control it. This story is widely believed to be the reason that Facebook
purchased Instagram and WhatsApp.
110
Alternatively, platforms may create “kill-zones” around themselves.
111
For example, Facebook
and Twitter’s aggressive API foreclosure, acquisition of competitors, and copying of new
services have boosted their market power.
112
Facebook even acquired a mobile phone monitoring
app, Onavo, which allows it to spot up-and-coming rivals and buy them or snuff them out.
113
While investment in innovation will continue, the type of innovation that will be funded will be
broadly determined by the incumbent and its strategies. Disruptive innovation in markets that are
characterized by high concentration levels and network effects is likely to be reduced compared
to a competitive market. One of the few sources of entry in digital platforms comes from rival
platforms that enter each other’s markets, as these large firms are more able to overcome entry
barriers of all kinds.
FriendFeed, and tbh; Google has bought Nest Labs, DoubleClick, YouTube, Waze, AdMob, Teracent,
BeatThatQuote.com, Admeld, and Tenor. See List of Mergers and Acquisitions by Amazon, W
IKIPEDIA (Apr. 12,
2019), https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_mergers_and_acquisitions_by_Amazon; List of Mergers and
Acquisitions by Facebook, W
IKIPEDIA (Mar. 25, 2019),
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_mergers_and_acquisitions_by_Facebook; List of Mergers and Acquisitions by
Alphabet, W
IKIPEDIA (Apr. 12, 2019),
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_mergers_and_acquisitions_by_Alphabet. At times, these firms have barely
bothered to disguise their anticompetitive purpose. See Jacob Kastrenakes, Facebook is Shutting Down a Teen App it
Bought Eight Months Ago, Along with Two Others That Languished, V
ERGE (July 2, 2018),
https://www.theverge.com/2018/7/2/17528896/facebook-tbh-moves-hello-shut-down-low-usage.
110
Tim Wu, The Case for Breaking Up Facebook and Instagram, WASH. POST (Sept. 28, 2018),
https://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2018/09/28/case-breaking-up-facebook-instagram.
111
Google’s, Facebook’s, and Amazon’s annual conferences “held to announce new tools, features, and acquisitions,
always ‘send shock waves of fear through entrepreneurs,’” according to one investment firm, and “[v]enture
capitalists attend to see which of their companies are going to get killed next.The Future of Tech Startups: Into the
Danger Zone, E
CONOMIST (U.K. edition) (June 2, 2018), at 61, http://weblogibc-co.com/wp-
content/uploads/2018/06/The_Economist_UK_Edition_-_June_02_2018.pdf.
112
See notes Error! Bookmark not defined.-Error! Bookmark not defined., supra; see, also, e.g., Erin Griffith,
Will Facebook Kill All Future Facebooks?, W
IRED (Oct. 25, 2017), https://www.wired.com/story/facebooks-
aggressive-moves-on-startups-threaten-innovation.
113
See Deepa Seetharaman & Betsy Morris, Facebook’s Onavo Gives Social-Media Firm Inside Peek at Rivals’
Users, W
ALL ST. J. (Aug. 13, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/facebooks-onavo-gives-social-media-firm-inside-
peek-at-rivals-users-1502622003l.
55
iii. The Reward for Innovation
Entrepreneurs may expect a low payoff to developing a free-standing product because of entry
barriers and exclusionary conduct by the incumbent platform. In that case, its best hope is to be
the preferred innovator of a complement and sell its business to the platform at an early stage.
This source of financial reward is often cited as a reason why large platform acquisitions are
good for society. Certainly, a reward of this type (a share in the platform’s business model and
flow of rents) is better than no payoff and will stimulate some level of innovation. However, it is
important to see that this incentive is distorted relative to that of the competitive context.
Suppose public policy could reduce entry barriers and prevent anticompetitive exclusionary
conduct towards entrants. In that case, the entrepreneur would not have to settle for a small
fraction of the platform’s profits, but could compete for all of them and try to replace the
platform. When a young firm has a chance to compete for the entire market on the merits of its
innovation because there is no exclusionary conduct holding it back, success could lead to up to
100% of market profits, rather than a smaller acquisition payoff.
114
The availability of this option
would allow entrepreneurs to develop improvements, complements, or replacements for a
platform according to what has the highest returns. The inability to innovate in pursuit of the
whole market leads to lower entry in tech sectors that are already dominated by a single large
company.
iv. Current Trends in Innovation
The incipient but growing technical research supports a concern for the impact of big tech on
innovation. Much of this research uses startup formation and its fuel, venture capital, as a proxy
for innovation. In 2018, Facebook commissioned the consulting firm Oliver Wyman to write a
report on this topic.
115
Using Facebook, Google, and Amazon as a proxy for big tech platforms,
the authors drew four conclusions: i) Facebook, Google, and Amazon contribute a very small
portion of the total venture capital in tech; ii) Facebook, Google, and Amazon M&A activity has
no impact on aggregate investment levels; iii) Facebook, Google, and Amazon R&D has had no
impact on venture capital investment levels; and iv) the presence of Facebook, Google, and
Amazon does not dampen venture capital investment in technology relative to other mature
sectors.
The first three conclusions are factual and unsurprising. But the fourth conclusion, that the
presence of Facebook, Google, and Amazon does not dampen VC activity related to other
114
As previously noted, many of these markets will tend toward concentration naturally, so the size of profits is not
affected by effective competition enforcement, but the number of years they can be earned will be affected when an
incumbent cannot block entrants.
115
Assessing the Impact of Big Tech on Venture Investment, OLIVER WYMAN (July 11, 2018),
https://www.oliverwyman.com/content/dam/oliver-wyman/v2/publications/2018/july/assessing-impact.pdf.
56
sectors, is surprising. Ian Hathaway has summarized a straightforward rebuttal.
116
The Facebook-
commissioned report looked at industry-wide effects. However, as Hathaway points out, viewing
the industry in the aggregate masks the effects of dominating firms. By looking at the sub-
industries associated with each firm—social platforms (Facebook), internet software (Google),
and internet retail (Amazon)—a different trend emerges. Since 2009, change in startup investing
in these sub-industries has fared poorly compared to the rest of software for Google and
Facebook, the rest of retail for Amazon, and the rest of all VC for each of Google, Facebook, and
Amazon. This suggests the existence of so-called “kill-zones,” that is, areas where venture
capitalists are reluctant to enter due to small prospects of future profits.
117
In a study of the mobile app market, Wen Wen and Feng Zhu come to a similar conclusion: Big
tech platforms do dampen innovation at the margin.
118
Their study analyzed how Android app
developers adjust their innovation strategies in response to entry (or threat of entry) by Google:
[A]fter Google’s entry threat increases, affected developers reduce innovation and raise
the prices for the affected apps. Once Google enters, the developers reduce innovation
and increase prices further. However, app developers’ incentives to innovate are not
completely suppressed; rather, they shift innovation to unaffected and new apps. Given
many apps already offering similar features, Google’s entry may reduce social
inefficiency.
119
Ultimately, these studies are suggestive but not determinative. Much more research needs to be
done to property identify the existence and extent of “kill zones” for market entry and
innovation. Nonetheless, the evidence thus far does suggest that current digital platforms face
very little threat of entry and are negatively impacting investment in key digital areas. This is
reinforced by the fact that the key players in this industry remained the same over the last two
technology waves, staying dominant through the shift to mobile and the rise of AI.
120
In the past,
116
Ian Hathaway, Platform Giants and Venture-Backed Startups, IAN HATHAWAY BLOG (Oct. 12, 2018),
http://www.ianhathaway.org/blog/2018/10/12/platform-giants-and-venture-backed-startups.
117
Id.
118
Wen & Zhu, supra note 4.
119
Id.
120
This dynamic affects where we see innovation, and by whom. While distributed technology seems to be a
relatively open playing field with the potential for many entrants, the bulk of innovation in other spaces is dominated
by tech giants. This is the case, for example, in the AI and voice-assistant space. In the AI field, innovation is driven
by startups leveraging and customizing the existing technology and libraries developed by Microsoft, Amazon,
Facebook, and Google. These companies have been quick to acquire promising ventures. Since 2011, Facebook has
acquired seven AI startups: Face, Protogeo, Wit.ai, Bloomsbury AI, Dreambit, Grokstyle, and Ozlo. Since 2010,
Amazon has also acquired seven startups in the AI space: Yap, ORbeu, GoButler, harvest.ai, Graphiq, Body Labs,
and Dispatch. Finally, Google has acquired 20 AI startups since 2011, the most notable being Kraggle and
DeepMind. See List of Mergers and Acquisitions by Facebook, supra note 109; List of Mergers and Acquisitions by
Alphabet, supra note 109. The AI space may not see a successful IPO because of these dynamics. Similarly,
innovation in voice-assistant technology has been dominated by tech giants. Microsoft’s Cortana, Apple’s Siri,
Google’s Google Voice, and Amazon’s Alexa are examples of dominant firms leveraging their previous offerings to
retain a first-mover advantage in the market.
57
dominant business found it difficult to navigate innovation or disruption waves. By contrast,
Facebook, Google, Amazon, Apple, and even Microsoft were able to ride these waves without
significant impact on market share or profit margins. This indirect evidence corroborates the
argument that these companies are facing few competitive threats.
There is an informal sense from practitioners that in mobile, cloud computing, and AI the result
is the same: Innovation at the core has slowed and is centered around the tech giants.
121
As a
result, new innovation waves have emerged, centering around blockchain, distributed ledgers,
and decentralized models (the new Silicon Valley growth paradigm); and with specialized AI,
niche retail applications, or, in the enterprise sector, b2b models. It should be noted that, apart
from blockchain, whose decentralization eliminates network effects (in theory), the other areas of
innovation do not necessarily herald a change in future market structure. Some have also argued
that, in markets that are characterized by significant market power, innovation will likely shift
from focusing on consumer benefit (to entice a rise in market share), to consumer exploitation.
122
In summary, unlike last-century’s businesses, digital businesses will often lack competition in
the market. This absence may be redressed by intensive competition for the market, as firms
compete to be the winner that takes all. However, if dominant firms are able to maintain their
dominance, even as the external environment and tastes change over time, consumers may be
denied the benefits of competition for the market as well.
f. Old Wine in a New Bottle, or a New Reality?
The market characteristics and problems discussed above in Part I and Part II raise an important
question: Is there something new or different about the digital economy, which justifies a revised
approach to intervention? Is this simply old wine in a new bottle, the same old problems of
network effects and concentration, or do we face a new reality? As we outlined above, we
believe the digital platform may be a unique combination of economic forces that requires both
new analysis and new public policy.
We expect some to argue that there is no need for action. It is in the interest of the powerful
incumbent to deny there is any problem to solve in order to delay while the market remains in its
hands. The waiting game allows incumbents to collect profit from the status quo and use those
profits to raise doubts or marginalize concerns in order to delay or prevent effective
intervention.
123
121
See, e.g., Griffith, note 112, supra; Tech Monopolies Are Stifling U.S. Innovation. Antitrust Enforcement May Help,
B
RINK NEWS (Dec. 11, 2018), http://www.brinknews.com/is-antitrust-enforcement-the-wests-best-weapon-against-
chinese-tech; Andreeson Horowitz Makes Big Bet on Blockchain, R
EALDAILY (Feb. 13, 2018),
https://realdaily.com/andreessen-horowitz-makes-big-bet-on-blockchain.
122
See Ezrachi & Stucke, supra note 14.
123
See, e.g., Brody Mullins & Jack Nicas, Pay Professors: Inside Google’s Academic Influence Campaign, WALL
ST. J. (July 14, 2017), https://www.wsj.com/articles/paying-professors-inside-googles-academic-influence-
58
Of course, the rapid developments of our digital world are not yet fully understood and merit
ongoing study. However, the material above makes clear that when market power becomes
entrenched, it is difficult to return to a competitive market. Inaction could create decades of
market power leading to weakened innovation, increased rent extraction, and social domination
by gatekeeper tech firms. Making no policy change and standing back to let platforms carry out
the strategies of their choice carries unusual risk. The new reality of the digital landscape
presents new challenges that will not easily be resolved through organic competition or current
US antitrust enforcement norms. The United States now risks missing the moment to confront a
serious challenge to competition. That risk spurs our search for possible solutions, which we
outline in Part IV.
campaign-1499785286 (relating Google’s funding of professors for, among other things, research opposing antitrust
intervention in the search engine market).
59
IV. SOLUTIONS
In this part, we outline a range of solutions to address the issues raised above. Needless to say,
there is no magic pill. The legislature, judiciary, and regulators will each need to play a role.
Each of the proposed solutions brings with it benefits and costs and should be considered as part
of a balanced policy. Still, with these limitations in mind, these solutions have the power to
address changing market dynamics and enable society to move toward a more efficient, open,
and dynamic market environment.
Competition policy is only one facet of society’s wider goals. Alongside the promotion of
competition policy, policymakers may wish to implement policies to promote privacy,
democratic accountability, and fairness. While these goals may be advanced indirectly through
the measures proposed below, they can also be addressed more directly through laws and
regulations that we do not consider here. Other committees provide valuable insights on possible
advancements on that front.
Having established the impact of high entry barriers, we open with a fundamental question about
the ability of a market to self-correct.
a. Will Markets Self-Correct When Competition Problems Arise?
The question whether the market will self-correct is central to antitrust policy. It affects the scope
of illegality, as well as the zeal with which competition agencies approach intervention. It also
affects the gain from implementing both ex ante and ex post solutions to insufficient
competition. When there is a reasonable chance that technological progress and innovation will
speedily prevent or remove bottlenecks and maintain an active competitive process, intervention
should be limited. For example, the stock trading app Robinhood Markets, which slashed per-
trade fees to zero, has forced competitors to scramble—even JP Morgan is now offering a free
stock trading app for consumers.
124
Likewise, Amazon and Wal-Mart are currently vigorously
competing for fast and cheap delivery services, forcing others to follow.
125
Acolytes of the Chicago School have persuaded many federal officials and judges that markets
will generally quickly self-correct, and that antitrust scrutiny should therefore be limited. This
124
See Hugh Son, JP Morgan to Unveil New Investing App With an Eye-Catching, Disruptive price: Free, CNBC
(Aug. 21, 2018), https://www.cnbc.com/2018/08/21/jp-morgan-to-unveil-new-investing-app-with-an-eye-catching-
disruptive-price-free.html.
125
See Suman Bhattacharyya, To Compete with Amazon, Walmart and eBay are Spending on Logistics, DIGIDAY
(Jan. 15, 2019), https://digiday.com/retail/compete-amazon-walmart-ebay-investing-logistics;
Andrea Cheng, Amazon, Facing Growing Competition, Offers Free Shipping on All Orders for the First Time,
F
ORBES (Nov. 5, 2018), https://www.forbes.com/sites/andriacheng/2018/11/05/amazon-free-shipping-holiday-
minimum-order-walmart-target/#6c459dc555e1; Nick Statt, Amazon and Walmart’s Rivalry is Reshaping How We’ll
Buy Everything in the Future, V
ERGE (Aug. 3, 2018), https://www.theverge.com/2018/8/3/17630604/amazon-
walmart-competition-tech-partnerships-grocery-delivery.
60
conviction has extended into digital markets. Opponents of government intervention point to the
dynamic nature of technology, the role of disruptive innovation, and firms’ strong investment in
research and development. They defend the adequacy of a free-market, noninterventionist
approach, and argue that the cost of over-intervention outweighs the benefits of intervention.
While some markets may self-correct, the findings of this report suggest that rapid self-
correction in markets dominated by large digital platforms is unlikely, and that harms to
economic welfare from the exercise of market power in such markets are substantial. As
discussed above, entrants find it difficult to overcome the high barriers to take on digital platform
incumbents. Economies of scale, economies of scope, network effects, and negligible marginal
cost all work together to make entry difficult in existing markets. Moreover, while monopoly
profits are a lure to competitors, incumbents can use those very profits to entrench themselves
and protect their position. No matter how dynamic the technology, an entrant will not unseat a
monopolist if the monopolist is permitted to buy the dynamic entrant for a share of monopoly
profits. Both parties gain from such a transaction—and the public loses.
The result is less entry than a more competitive environment would create. Less entry into digital
markets means fewer choices for consumers, stunted development of alternative paths of
innovation, higher prices, and lower quality. Self-correction is not a realistic expectation in this
environment—indeed, the available evidence suggests it has not happened—and public policy
should not rely exclusively on it. Effective antitrust enforcement and regulation must take
account of this reality. If there is a force toward self-correction, it may require active promotion
to succeed, and in this way public intervention can be complementary rather than antagonistic to
market forces. Indeed, the other reports that have addressed this problem around the world have
accepted that policy changes are necessary in order to avoid stagnant and harmful digital
markets. We now turn to what policy options exist, and which of these the government might
adopt.
b. US Antitrust
i. Basic Principles
Antitrust law is intended to prohibit private conduct by firms that reduces economic welfare.
Although application of antitrust principles can be complex and the specific doctrinal
embodiments of those principles can seem arcane and arbitrary, at its core US antitrust law is
simple.
126
It can be summarized in a single sentence: Private conduct that creates or increases
market power, other than by efficiency-based competition on the merits, is illegal.
There are two fundamental components of any antitrust violation. The first is bad conduct,
commonly called “anticompetitive conduct.” The second is a resulting harm to economic welfare
126
See A. Douglas Melamed, Response: Antitrust Law is Not That Complicated, 130 HARV. L. REV. F. 163 (2019).
61
from the creation of more market power than would otherwise exist. A firm gains market power
when the competitive discipline imposed upon that firm by either actual or potential future rivals
is reduced. One way to achieve market power is through price-fixing and other forms of
collusion, but we will not address such behaviors here. Rather, this report will focus on antitrust
law as it applies to mergers and non-merger exclusionary conduct.
Importantly, a firm does not violate the antitrust laws if it gains market power by competing on
the merits rather than as a result of anticompetitive conduct. For example, if a firm enters the
market with a fantastic new product that has strong network effects, competes solely on the
merits of that product with no anticompetitive conduct, and finds itself with 95% market share, it
would not have violated the antitrust laws. Similarly, a firm does not violate the antitrust laws if
it engages in anticompetitive conduct but that conduct does not harm the market as a whole and
fails to result in additional market power.
127
127
Certain types of conduct, notably agreements among competitors fixing prices or allocating customers or service
areas, are regarded as unlawful per se, which means that they are unlawful without proof of harm to competition in
the market as a whole. Per se illegality in these circumstances is not a rejection of the principle described in this text.
Rather, per se illegality reflects a pragmatic judgment that those types of conduct are so likely to harm competition
and so unlikely to provide any welfare benefits that it would be needlessly costly and burdensome to require proof of
harm to the market as a whole on a case-by-case basis.
Box IV
More About US Antitrust Law
There are four substantive elements to any US antitrust violation: Private, as opposed to
government, conduct; anticompetitive conduct; creation or increase in market power; and a causal
connection between the conduct and the market power. There are three basic types of conduct that
can be anticompetitive. They are (i) mergers that lessen competition, (ii) conduct that excludes or
weakens actual or potential rivals, and (iii) conduct that constitutes or facilitates collusion (e.g.
cartels) among firms that would otherwise compete more vigorously. Possible antitrust problems
involving digital platforms are most likely to arise from the first two types of conduct.
Anticompetitive conduct is conduct that is likely to lead to the creation or maintenance of market
power for reasons other than an increase in allocative efficiency (i.e., by increasing output or
decreasing price where price is not less than marginal cost) or productive efficiency (i.e., by
reducing cost or increasing product quality). The range of potential anticompetitive conduct is
nearly boundless and can include burning down a rival’s factory, designing products to be
incompatible with rivals’ products, acquiring smaller rivals to shut them down or deny them to
other suitors, exclusive dealing and Most Favored Nation clauses (MFNs) in some circumstances,
and some forms of tying or bundling multiple products or services. Digital markets are prone to
new and innovative violations of the antitrust laws because marginal costs are often close to zero,
the business models themselves are often new and innovative, and firms are able to be creative
with new product bundles, contracts, and transactions.
62
More About US Antitrust Law (Cont.)
Current popular debate often seems to imply that high market share in and of itself is a violation
of the antitrust laws. It is important to understand that a firm can violate the antitrust laws only
if it engages in anticompetitive conduct, even if its conduct causes the firm to gain monopoly
power. Thus, for example, a firm does not violate the antitrust laws by gaining market power
solely because it has a better product that consumers choose to buy for that reason or because it
develops a better distribution channels that consumers find convenient.
Since at least the middle of the twentieth century, US antitrust law has embraced the view that
those who do not engage in anticompetitive conduct are entitled to the fruits of their labor,
including any market power or dominance that they might have gained. This view rests on the
concern that breaking up or restricting firms that obtain their success by competition on the
merits would deter the very kind of aggressive but procompetitive conduct that the antitrust
laws are intended to encourage. Such no-fault intervention would deter such conduct, both
because firms would fear that too much success would end up hurting them and because they
would be uncertain about the antitrust implications of their conduct. While firms that achieve
durable market power, especially in industries that are regarded as “natural monopolies,” are
sometimes subject to sectoral regulation, durable market power is not itself a sufficient basis for
antitrust intervention. Society has other legal mechanisms to regulate an industry that is not
delivering on social goals.
US antitrust law has also long required that antitrust plaintiffs prove, not just anticompetitive
conduct, but also that the conduct harmed competition in the market as a whole.
1
This
requirement limits antitrust enforcement to those matters that are important enough to warrant
costly and burdensome antitrust proceedings and ensures that antitrust law remains focused on
making markets work.
Both the anticompetitive requirement and the market power requirement protect the competitive
process, another concern that arises in the popular debate. The conduct requirement does this by
focusing antitrust enforcement on conduct that is not efficiency-based and can thus create
market power only by distorting competition on the merits. The market power requirement does
this by focusing antitrust enforcement on conduct that impairs the competitive discipline of
rivals and, in that way, harms the competitive process. Many of the current proposals for more
aggressive antitrust enforcement, although couched in antitrust language, would dispense with
either the bad conduct requirement or the market power requirement.
Conduct that harms competition without creating any efficiencies can readily be characterized
as anticompetitive. Examples of such conduct include mergers among competitors that do not
create efficiencies by combining complementary assets, conduct whose only purpose is to harm
or exclude competitors, and agreements among competitors about their prices or other terms of
trade.
1 See Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1977) (“The antitrust laws . . . were
enacted for the protection of competition, not competitors.”) (internal citation and quote marks omitted).
63
While US antitrust law has long been flexible in combatting anti-competitive conduct, there is
increasing concern that it has been underenforced in recent years. First, there is increasing
evidence that the enforcement agencies and courts have permitted too many mergers between
competing firms that have led to post-merger price increases and other indications of increased
More About US Antitrust Law (Cont.)
When conduct both generates efficiencies and impairs the competitive efficacy of rivals, the
question whether it is anticompetitive is less clear and will depend on specific facts. The
conduct is more likely to be unlawful if substantially all of the efficiencies could be achieved
by an alternative that is less harmful to rivals or if the efficiencies are insubstantial and the
harm to rivals is great. Courts rarely deem conduct anticompetitive if it generates substantial
efficiencies that cannot be realized by an available alternative, regardless of the impact of that
conduct on rivals.
As explained in greater detail below, antitrust enforcement decisions are often made with
great uncertainty about the efficiencies and market impact of the conduct at issue. For the
past 30 years or so, antitrust law has reflected the view that mistakes in the direction of over-
enforcement are more problematic than those in the direction of under-enforcement. One
premise of this view is that under-enforcement results in market problems that are likely to be
corrected by innovation or other market developments. As noted above, this report assesses
the state of the evidence on entry and innovation and concludes that such self-correction is
unlikely to be prompt and effective, in part because digital platforms that have achieved
market power possess formidable barriers that inhibit entry and innovation. The assumption
that over-enforcement is costly is reflected in aspects of antitrust doctrine applicable to
exclusionary conduct, vertical contracts, and merger review as well as in courts holding
antitrust plaintiffs to demanding standards of proof.
The relative concerns about the risks and cost of over-enforcement and under-enforcement
embodied in current antitrust law has been subject to increasing criticism. This report
concludes that the tolerance of antitrust law for under-enforcement should be reassessed and
recalibrated. Careful recalibration of the benefits and costs of different mistakes is likely
essential to the development of more aggressive antitrust law that remains consistent with the
principles described above.
64
market power.
128
Vertical mergers are rarely challenged by the enforcement agencies,
129
and
claimed or expected merger-related efficiencies are often not realized. Second, monopsony—
market power of buyers or employers—appears to be a growing problem.
130
Recent studies
suggest that labor markets are less competitive than previously thought and employers have
exercised market power against workers in those markets.
131
Third, there have been few antitrust
challenges to exclusionary conduct since the government’s 1998 case against Microsoft, and
courts have in several instances been hostile to such cases and have imposed daunting proof
requirements on plaintiffs. Apparent under-enforcement is in part due to courts’ reliance on so-
called Chicago School assumptions that do not have a sound theoretical or empirical basis.
Regardless of whether or not antitrust enforcement has failed to keep up with conduct in the
economy more generally, the challenge of enforcing in the area of digital platforms presents new
issues. The platforms create new competitive environments; they provide opportunities for new
types of anticompetitive conduct; and they create new economic and conceptual challenges for
antitrust enforcement. This section is focused on analysis and recommendations designed to help
such future enforcement, though that enforcement will often be addressed to conduct that
occurred in the past.
The challenges facing future antitrust enforcement are more than just analytical and intellectual.
Antitrust law and its application by the courts over the past several decades have reflected the
128
See JOHN KWOKA, MERGERS, MERGER CONTROL, AND REMEDIES: A RETROSPECTIVE ANALYSIS OF U.S. POLICY
156, 159 (2014); Jonathan B. Baker, Presentation, Has the US Economy Become More Concentrated and Less
Competitive: A Review of the Data (Sept. 13, 2018),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/1398386/georgetown-deck-913.pdf, at 39 (listing six
reasons to believe that industry concentration cannot be explained by scale economics, including the fact that
various forms of anticompetitive behavior are “insufficiently deterred” and that “market power is durable”); John E.
Kwoka, The Structural Presumption and the Safe Harbor in Merger Review: False Positives or Unwarranted
Concerns?, 81 A
NTITRUST L.J. 837 (2017); John Kwoka, The Changing Nature of Efficiencies in Mergers and in
Merger Analysis, 60(3) A
NTITRUST BULL. 231 (2015); Leemore Dafny et al., Paying a Premium on Your Premium?
Consolidation in the US Health Insurance Industry 102 A
MER. ECON. REV. 1161, 1163 (2012) (“[T]he mean
increase in local market [firm concentration] between 1998 and 2006 (inclusive) raised premiums by roughly 7
percent from their 1998 baseline”); Orley Ashenfelter & Daniel Hosken, The Effect of Mergers on Consumer Prices:
Evidence from Five Mergers on the Enforcement Margin, 53 J.L.
& ECON. 417 (2010). But see Michael Vita & F.
David Osinski, John Kwoka's Mergers, Merger Control, and Remedies: A Critical Review, 82 A
NTITRUST L.J. 361
(2018). See also Robert B. Kulick, Ready-to-Mix: Horizontal Mergers, Prices, and Productivity (U.S. Census
Bureau, Ctr. for Econ. Studies, Working Paper No. 17-38, 2017), https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2637961; Bruce
A. Blonigen & Justin R. Pierce, Evidence for the Effects of Mergers on Market Power and Efficiency (NBER,
Working Paper No. 22750, 2016), https://www.nber.org/papers/w22750, at 24.
129
See D. Bruce Hoffman, Acting Director, Bureau of Competition, Fed. Trade Comm’n, Vertical Merger
Enforcement at the FTC, Address at the Credit Suisse 2018 Washington Perspectives Conference (Jan. 10, 2018),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/1304213/hoffman_vertical_merger_speech_final.pdf
(admitting that “vertical merger enforcement is . . . a small part of [the FTC’s] merger workload”).
130
See, e.g., Michael Kades, In Conversation with Herbert Hovenkamp and Ioana Marinescu, EQUITABLE GROWTH
(Oct. 11, 2018), https://equitablegrowth.org/in-conversation-with-herbert-hovenkamp-and-ioana-marinescu.
131
Elena Preger & Matt Schmitt, Employer Consolidation and Wages: Evidence from Hospitals (Washington Center
for Equitable Growth Working Paper, 2019), https://equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/employer-consolidation-
and-wages-evidence-from-hospitals.
65
now outdated learning of an earlier era of economic thought, and they appear in some respects
inhospitable to new learning. Antitrust enforcement better suited to the challenges of the Digital
Age may therefore require new legislation.
Box V
EU Competition Law
EU competition law, like US antitrust law and the competition laws of most nations, is
intended in large part to promote economic welfare by prohibiting private conduct that
injures or is likely to injure competition. Not surprisingly in light of this shared objective, US
and EU law are very similar.
With respect to market power, similar to US antitrust law, a firm does not violate the EU
Competition laws if it gains power by competing on the merits rather than as a result of
anticompetitive conduct. EU Competition law only condemns the abuse of a dominant position.
An abuse, under EU law, may however include a wider range of prohibited exclusionary and
exploitative practices than under US antitrust law. As a result, some practices which may not
trigger enforcement action under US antitrust law, may nonetheless be regarded as infringing
EU competition law.
In this context, it is also worth noting the (wider) goals of EU competition law. According to
the European Commission, competition on the market is protected ‘as a means of enhancing
consumer welfare and of ensuring an efficient allocation of resources.’
1
This notwithstanding,
EU competition law has also consistently been held to protect ‘not only the interests of
competitors or of consumers, but also the structure of the market and, in so doing, competition
as such.’
2
Moreover, a genuinely indigenous objective is worthy of note, namely that of
promoting European market integration.
3
The multitude of competition goals, and their position within the wider normative EU values
may sometimes contribute to possible inconsistencies between the EU and US analysis.
4
EU Competition law is enforced both at public and private levels; public enforcement is carried
out by the European Commission and by the Competition Authorities of the member states.
Private enforcement takes place in the courts of the member states, where private parties may
bring follow-on or stand-alone damage claims.
1 European Commission, ‘Guidelines on the Application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty’ [2004] OJ C101/97,
para.13 (hereinafter ‘the General Guidelines’).
2 Case C-501/06 P GlaxoSmithKline Services Unlimited v Commission and Others [2009] ECR I-9291, para 63.
See also Case C-8/08 T-Mobile Netherlands and Others [2009] ECR I-4529, paras 31, 36, 38-39; Council
Regulation (EC) 1/2003 on the Implementation of the Rules on Competition Laid Down in Articles 81 and 82 of
the Treaty [2003] OJ L1/1, Recital 9; European Commission, ‘Green Paper on Vertical Restraints in EC
Competition Policy’ COM(96) 721 final, para 180.
3 Information Service High Authority of the European Community for Coal and Steel Luxembourg, ‘The Brussels
Report on the General Common Market’ (June 1956) (Spaak Report); David J Gerber, ‘The Transformation of
European Community Competition Law?’ [1994] Harvard Intl LJ 97, 102.
4 Ezrachi, Ariel, EU Competition Law Goals and the Digital Economy (June 6, 2018). Oxford Legal Studies
Research Paper No. 17/2018. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3191766
66
c. Special Challenges Presented by Technology Platforms
Technology platforms present particular challenges for antitrust enforcement. Markets tip and
resulting market power is durable, so even effective antitrust enforcement is unlikely to generate
fragmented markets. Nonetheless, enforcement that protects competition on the merits in the first
stage and prevents exclusionary conduct in the second stage will help ensure that market-
participants make unfettered choices among competing platforms and that entry and innovation
are not inhibited by private rent-seeking. Additionally, these markets move very quickly in areas
such as new product introduction, foreclosure, and tipping. Antitrust litigation does not move
quickly. Effective antitrust enforcement should move as rapidly as is practicable. However,
enforcers will be most effective when they choose enforcement priorities and remedies to
generate optimal deterrence of anticompetitive conduct.
As explained above, digital platforms are able to exploit behavioral biases to their advantage.
Economists describe these strategies as falling into two conceptually distinct categories of
conduct: exclusive (strategies that foreclose competition) and collusive (strategies that cause
higher prices).
132
The former occurs when platforms exploit behavioral biases to keep consumers
attached to their platforms and make switching to alternatives more difficult. These tactics
generally make consumers less receptive to competitive alternatives—they lower
contestability—and thus raise entry barriers. Platforms also exploit behavioral biases—such as
hyperbolic discounting and limited self-control—to extract surplus from both consumers and
content providers. Strategies such as offering addictive content at moments when consumers lack
self-control increase time spent on the platform and profitable ad sales even as the platform
lowers the quality of content. These tactics increase the welfare costs of market power.
Many technology platforms are distinctive because they provide valued services to consumers
without charging a monetary price. Instead, consumers barter their attention and data to the
platforms in exchange for these services. The platforms use that attention and data to generate
monetary payments from advertisers. While a barter transaction is, in principle, subject to
antitrust scrutiny just like any other transaction, antitrust enforcement has had vastly more
experience with transactions based on monetary prices, and that experience has prompted the
development of sophisticated tools to analyze money prices.
133
Where monetary prices are fixed
at zero while quality changes over timein response to changes to the nature of the services,
privacy protections, content offerings and the like—the quality-adjusted prices change. Because
economists, antitrust agencies, and courts have less experience with quality, they lack equally
132
See Steven C. Salop, Practices that (Credibly) Facilitate Oligopoly Co-ordination, in NEW DEVELOPMENTS
IN THE ANALYSIS OF MARKET STRUCTURE 265 (Joseph E. Stiglitz & G. Frank Mathewson eds., 1986
133
For example, the US agencies’ traditional definition of an antitrust market is one in which a monopolist could
profitably raise price by a non-insignificant amount for a significant period of time. See U.S.
DEPT OF JUST. & FED.
TRADE COMMN, 2010 HORIZONTAL MERGER GUIDELINES (2010),
https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/attachments/merger-review/100819hmg.pdf, at 9, § 4.1 (defining the
hypothetical monopolist test).
67
sophisticated tools for analyzing changes in quality-based prices. This is partially because quality
naturally presents itself in a less quantified form than price, but also because in regular markets
price often adjusts to quality, not the other way around, so economists have been able to rely on
price as one measure of quality. When enforcers are able to quantitatively link quality to price,
they will be better equipped to fit digital cases into older, price-centered jurisprudence.
Technology platforms also pose unusual challenges for antitrust merger enforcement. To the
extent that platforms are in winner-take-all or winner-take-most markets, mergers among
significant, existing competitors, which are the mergers most subject to antitrust challenge, are
likely to be rare. Instead, competition in such markets is largely for the future, often in evolving
and very different markets. This competition is sometimes called “competition for the market” or
“leapfrog” competition. In this context, acquisition by a dominant platform of a much smaller
and possibly nascent firm could be very damaging to competition if, absent the acquisition, the
smaller firm would develop into a major competitive threat or would lead to significant change
in the nature of the market. In a concentrated market structure, this potential competition from
very small entrants may be the most important source of competition faced by the incumbent
firm.
134
The problem is that it is very difficult to know at the time of an acquisition whether the acquired
firm is likely to develop into a competitor or whether, to the contrary, acquisition by the platform
offers the most promising path to the commercial development and use of the acquired firm’s
new technology or an essential exit strategy for investors in the acquired firm. Antitrust agencies
and antitrust law need to develop a better understanding of the circumstances under which
acquisitions of nascent competitors might be anticompetitive.
135
Enforcers may have to learn to
think more as venture capitalists do and understand their analytics in order to better identify
134
The D.C. Circuit in Microsoft endorsed this principle. See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 79
(D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam) (“[I]t would be inimical to the purpose of the Sherman Act to allow
monopolists free reign to squash nascent, albeit unproven, competitors at will.”).
135
In addition, because small acquisitions are not subject to pre-merger review under the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act,
agencies are often unaware of the acquisitions until after the are consummated. The threshold for pre-merger
notification was raised in December 2000 from $10 million to $50 million. While transactions under the threshold
are still subject to Clayton Act enforcement, agencies do not see them in advance, may not find them at all, and can
only sue to unwind them after the fact. After the filing threshold increase, there was a sharp uptick of newly non-
notified mergers (between $10 and $50 million) between direct competitorsthe type of mergers that likely would
have been blocked during HSR review, had it occurred. Small technology mergers fall in this category also and are
rarely reviewed or challenged. See Thomas Wollman, Stealth Consolidation: Evidence from an Amendment to the
Hart-Scott-Rodino Act, A
MER. ECON. REV. INSIGHTS (forthcoming 2019),
https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/aeri.20180137. An example of a problematic merger of this type that
was challenged by DOJ after consummation is Bazaarvoice-PowerReviews. United States v. Bazaarvoice, 3:13-cv-
00133-WHO, 2014 WL 203966 (N.D. Cal., Jan. 8, 2014). While the government prevailed in that litigation, because
the two software firms had gone some way down the integration path, the result was arguably not as favorable for
consumers as if the transaction had been notified and blocked ex ante which would have preserved two robust
competitors. In general, the evidence demonstrates that firms act quickly to obtain market power in the absence of
government enforcement, and that the requirement to notify the government serves as an important deterrent to
anticompetitive mergers.
68
harms. A pattern of repeated purchases of small potential competitors that could have developed
into substitutes, or an acquisition price that reflects a sharing of monopoly rents, might be useful
indicators of possible competitive risks.
Antitrust law might also have difficulty policing conduct by established technology firms that
tends to exclude or marginalize smaller rivals. Recall that at launch a platform invites and
encourages complementors to provide content and functionality on its platform. It does this when
it is competing for consumers’ attention against other platforms because it wants its platform to
be attractive. A successful platform creates an ecosystem that is valuable to consumers.
However, one or both of the following issues may arise. In the first, a complement to the
platform seeks to become its horizontal competitor. In the second, the platform seeks to become
a horizontal competitor of one of its complements. Let us take these one at a time.
First, a complement can develop the ability to form a relationship with the end user that is
sufficiently free-standing and valuable to take the user off the platform and into a separate
relationship with the complement. The platform has an incentive to foreclose the complement to
prevent this loss of market power and profit. Because the complement is transitioning into direct
horizontal rivalry with the platform, US law does not have any trouble recognizing antitrust
violations of this form. For example, content providers like Yelp are Google’s complements—
people want to be able to find Yelp reviews via Google—but Yelp is also a search engine that
could grow to rival Google search. Google has entered the restaurant review market with its map
product, and Yelp now alleges that Google is engaging in foreclosure.
136
Second, if the platform observes that a complement (say, complement Z) is earning strong
profits, the platform may seek to enter that complementary market. Because the platform and
rival complement Z providers are now horizontal competitors, the platform has the incentive—
and, often, the ability—to foreclose those competitors. This could take the form of banning rival
complements from the platform, reducing their ability to interoperate, raising their costs, steering
customers elsewhere, and so forth. If the platform’s new product Z is a wonderful innovation,
there will be an efficiency (in the form of higher quality) to weigh against any harms from less
competition.
137
At root, there is a fundamental question about whether all the rents of the
platform are part of the competitive return to the creator of the platform, particularly if the
complementors’ added-value can be driven to zero once the network effects are operational. In a
setting with single-homing users, those complements may have no bargaining power ex post and
the platform may have the incentive and ability to give them a share of zero. This is a
136
See Duhigg, supra note 23.
137
Lina Khan, Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox, 126 Yale L.J. 710, 780-83 (2017). See also Feng Zhu & Qihong Liu,
Competing with Complementors: An Empirical Look at Amazon.com, 39 S
TRAT. MGMT. J. 2618, 2618 (2018)
(finding that “[w]hile Amazon's entry discourages affected third‐party sellers from subsequently pursuing growth on
the platform, it increases product demand and reduces shipping costs for consumers”).
69
particularly interesting problem when those complementors added value to the platform at a
critical competitive moment before network effects and entry barriers protected it.
Addressing this issue, the U.K. Furman Report and the EC Vestager Report both devote
significant discussion to platforms being “fair” to complementors. First, a sectoral regulator is
likely to be better than the antitrust laws at enforcing fairness norms. Antitrust law is focused,
not on fairness itself, but on anticompetitive conduct that creates market power and might
therefore permit various types of conduct that some might regard as “unfair” because, for
example, a platform extracts the rents of partners that offer a good product but have no
bargaining power. Because the complementor is not threatening to replace the platform, the
simple exclusion theory of harm explained above does not apply directly. The situation is
informally akin to the familiar “open early, closed late” strategy.
138
In the “open early, closed
late,” strategy a firm at first encourages others to become dependent on connecting to it and
relying on it, and later uses their dependence to shut out competitors or extract monopoly
rents.
139
This type of behavior might be regarded as exploitation or excessive pricing and thus
deemed to be an unlawful abuse of dominance under EU law. It would violate US law only if,
among other things, it enabled the platform to gain or preserve market power it otherwise would
not have in either the platform market or the market in which the excluded firm did business. In
the latter case under US antitrust law, this conduct might be captured under the “duty to deal”
framework.
Because large technology platforms have huge scale and benefit from network effects, they are
often able to engage in aggressive conduct targeted at rivals without violating existing antitrust
standards. The platforms might be able to copy rivals’ innovations or otherwise increase the
value of their services to consumers without pricing below cost, and they might be able to insist
that rivals using their platforms enter into agreements, such as agreements regarding access to
consumer data, that enhance the platform’s ability to compete. A platform might be able to
require exclusive contracts or loyalty-based contracts that cause single-homing by one side (e.g.
drivers or consumers). Such single-homing might cause the market to tip in the platform’s favor
and exclude a competitor. This kind of conduct often has efficiency benefits that make it difficult
to challenge the conduct under the antitrust laws. Certain aspects of antitrust law might be
adjusted, for example antitrust rules intended to prohibit dominant firms from engaging in
conduct that would exclude an equally efficient competitor could be revised to better protect
138
See Scott A. Sher & Bradley T. Tennis, Exploiting Others’ Investments in Open Standards, COMPETITION POL.
INT. (Sept. 15, 2016), https://www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/exploiting-others-investments-in-open-
standards/; Carl Shapiro, Exclusionary Conduct: Testimony Before the Antitrust Modernization Commission (Sept.
29, 2005), http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/Shapiro/amcexclusion.pdf, at 15 (“[I]n a network industry, a firm might
obtain a dominant position based in part on certain ‘open’ policies that induce reliance by complementary firms, and
then later exploit that position by offering less favorable interconnection terms or by refusing to interconnect with
them altogether.”).
139
For an example, see the discussion of Cisco-Arista at note 16, supra, and accompanying text.
70
smaller competitors. Nonetheless, it is unlikely that such adjustments would entirely eliminate
the competitive advantages inherent in large firms with substantial scale and scope economies.
Pinpointing the locus of competition and therefore the relevant market in which technology
platforms compete can also be challenging because the markets are multisided and are often ones
with which economists and lawyers have little experience. This complexity can make market
definition another hurdle to effective enforcement. For example, two platforms might compete in
general search, while also each offering social media and mapping functionalities, among other
services. Advertisers that buy ads on searches may be a common set of customers. While courts
and agencies have substantial experience analyzing advertising markets, for example, they are
less knowledgeable about markets for attention or barter transactions involving data made
available to providers as an unintended byproduct of using a digital platform. The problems are
compounded by the facts that technologies surrounding the products’ functions in digital markets
are continually changing and changes in quality-adjusted prices are difficult to observe.
Only one litigated US case has explicitly addressed these issues. That case culminated in a 2018
decision by the US Supreme Court.
140
Although the decision has been praised by some
conservative commentators,
141
it has been widely criticized by others.
142
The case itself involved
the credit card business and what the Court called a “transaction platform,” in which the platform
(American Express) facilitated simultaneous transactions between consumers and merchants.
143
It should not, therefore, be legal precedent applicable to other kinds of platforms like Google and
Facebook. But the case does suggest that the five-Justice majority on the Court is hostile to
antitrust enforcement (at least in vertical and exclusion cases), does not understand multi-sided
markets very well, and might be more influenced by ideological preconceptions than by evidence
in the case or fact-finding by district court judges.
144
140
Ohio v. American Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018).
141
See, e.g., FED. TRADE COMMN, Transcript: FTC Hearing #3: Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st
Century (Session 4) (Oct. 15, 2018),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/1413712/ftc_hearings_session_3_transcript_day_1_10-
15-18.pdf, at 228-235 (Vinson & Elkins partner Darren Tucker praising the American Express decision).
142
See, e.g., Dennis W. Carlton, The Anticompetitive Effects of Vertical Most-Favored-Nation Restraints and the
Error of Amex, C
OLUM. BUS. L. REV. (forthcoming 2019),
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3328628; Herbert Hovenkamp, Platforms and the Rule of
Reason: The American Express Case, C
OLUM. BUS. L. REV. (forthcoming 2019),
https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=3060&context=faculty_scholarship; A. Douglas
Melamed & Nicolas Petit, The Misguided Assault on the Consumer Welfare Standard in the Age of Platform
Markets, 54 R
EV. INDUSTRIAL ORG. 1 (2019); Michael Katz & Jonathan Sallet, Multisided Platforms and Antitrust
Enforcement, 127 Y
ALE L J. 1724 (2018). See also FED. TRADE COMMN, supra note 141, at 226 (Goldstein &
Russell partner Eric Citron describing the American Express decision as “economically illiterate”).
143
American Express, 138 S. Ct. at 2277.
144
Anthony Kennedy, one of the members of the five-justice majority in American Express, has since retired, but his
replacement, Brett Kavanaugh, is likely even more ideological on antitrust matters. See Stephen Calkins, How Might
a Justice Kavanaugh Impact Antitrust Jurisprudence?, P
ROMARKET BLOG (July 20, 2018),
https://promarket.org/might-justice-kavanaugh-impact-antitrust-jurisprudence.
71
The harm from lack of competition in digital markets will manifest itself in quality and
innovation, as well as from higher prices to advertisers. As detailed by Giulio Federico and
colleagues, the impact on consumer welfare of a decline in innovation due to lack of competition
is likely to be large, especially in the case of fast-moving technologies that affect many
consumers and related businesses.
145
Very often the uncertainty involved in evaluating harms to
innovation will be high, especially in contrast to the analysis of price forecasts. It is possible to
measure pipeline projects and current R&D to obtain a sense of competitive overlap or
trajectory, but the tools do not yet exist to accurately forecast the speed and direction of
innovation in the longer run. Likewise, obtaining quantitative evidence about the innovations or
products that would have been offered to consumers in the absence of the conduct is often not
possible.
Perhaps in part as a result of these challenges, US antitrust has not been active in policing
allegedly anticompetitive conduct by technology platforms. The government’s last
monopolization case involving issues raised by platforms was the Microsoft case in 1998. Today,
the European Commission and the European National Competition Authorities effectively act as
the global enforcers for allegedly exclusionary conduct that operates at a global level in
industries such as software, chips, and digital platforms.
146
d. Could a Reformed Antitrust Law be Effective in Dealing with
Digital Platforms?
There are many ways that US antitrust law could be revised to make it more aggressive in
addressing competition problems while maintaining the objective of prohibiting private conduct
that reduces economic welfare. Such changes could improve competition enforcement in digital
markets as well as others.
i. Reform by What Means?
With few exceptions, antitrust law has in the past evolved in a common-law-like process by
which it has reflected new learning and judicial and market experience. This process is
continuing, at least to some extent, as antitrust law and enforcement have recognized, for
example, previously unnoticed competition problems in labor markets and doctrine has evolved
to incorporate new learning about competitive problems that can be created by most favored
145
Giulio Federico, Fiona Scott Morton, & Carl Shapiro, Antitrust and Innovation: Welcoming and Protecting
Disruption (NBER Innovation Policy and the Economy, Working Paper, 2019) (on file with authors).
146
See, e.g., Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission Fines Google €4.34 Billion for Illegal Practices
Regarding Android Mobile Devices to Strengthen Dominance of Google’s Search Engine (July 18, 2018),
http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-18-4581_en.htm; Press Release, Euro. Comm’n, Antitrust: Commission
Closes Formal Proceedings Against Qualcomm (Nov. 24, 2009), http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-09-
516_en.htm; Report on the Monitoring Exercise Carried Out in the Online Hotel Booking Sector by EU Competition
Authorities in 2016, E
URO. COMMN (2017), http://ec.europa.eu/competition/ecn/hotel_monitoring_report_en.pdf.
72
nation (MFN) and other vertical agreements. The challenges posed by the big technology
platforms and the current populist political climate have, however, put the issue of antitrust
reform before Congress in various legislative proposals. There are advantages and disadvantages
to both common law evolution and new legislation.
Evolution by a common law-like process takes time. It took the Chicago School roughly 20 years
to refocus antitrust law, from the early expressions of its perspective in 1950s and 1960s
147
until
the Supreme Court’s seminal decision in GTE Sylvania in 1977
148
and the obstacles are
probably greater now. While there had been ebbs and flows in antitrust enforcement in the mid-
twentieth century, there was not a well-formed conceptual framework calling for aggressive
enforcement that the Chicago School proponents had to overcome. The structure-conduct-
performance paradigm was widely accepted as an economic proposition, but it was not
embedded in a rigorous normative and conceptual antitrust framework. By contrast,
oversimplified Chicago School thinking has provided a widely accepted framework for antitrust
analysis for more than thirty years. Perhaps more importantly, many federal judges, appointed by
an increasingly ideological vetting process, are trained in and adherents of that framework. Many
seem unaware of new economic research that calls into question many of the tenets of that
framework and continue to cite outdated Chicago School publications of the 1970s and 1980s.
And, while there has been a great deal of economic research and literature on which a new
antitrust paradigm could be constructed, there is not a widely accepted, alternative paradigm that
is comprehensible to and administrable by lawyers and judges. Even if such a paradigm were
written tomorrow and rapidly became widely accepted, it would likely take years for that
paradigm to be manifest in doctrinal changes and market outcomes.
New legislation could in principle be adopted and take effect much more rapidly. New
legislation would not need to depart from the dual requirements of bad conduct and harm to
competition in the market as a whole. Such legislation might, instead, implement a recalibration
of the relative tolerance of antitrust law for the risk of over-enforcement and under-enforcement
by prescribing rebuttable presumptions that would ease the high proof requirements currently
imposed on antitrust plaintiffs and place on defendants a more rigorous burden of proving
efficiencies. Some possible new presumptions and similar reforms are outlined below.
The risk, of course, is that new legislation will not be enacted by experts committed to sound,
economically-focused antitrust. It will be designed by Congress in a politically charged
environment subject to pressure from the very companies who stand to lose their market power if
subject to increased antitrust oversight, or who benefit if their trading partners are subjected to
excessive oversight.
147
See, e.g., Ward S. Bowman Jr., Tying Arrangements and the Leverage Problem, 67 YALE L.J. (1957); Robert H.
Bork, Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act, 9 J.L.
& ECON. 7 (1966); Robert H. Bork & Ward S.
Bowman, Jr., The Crisis in Antitrust, F
ORTUNE, Dec. 1963, at 138, reprinted in 65 COLUM. L. REV. 363 (1965).
148
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
73
There is more at stake than the risk of flawed legislation. Antitrust law has maintained legitimacy
and widespread support for nearly 130 years in part because it applies to all forms of commercial
activity and is not perceived as special interest legislation. In our view it is very important that
antitrust law not have different rules aimed at different sectors—such as technology
149
or
agriculture
150
—that would differentiate industries and undermine political support for antitrust
law in general. For this reason, the report outlines a number of useful digital platform
interventions that can be undertaken by a sectoral regulator rather than falling to the task of
antitrust enforcement.
Equally important, antitrust law has benefited immensely from the brevity and vagueness of the
key statutory provisions because they have enabled antitrust law to evolve in response to new
learning. The challenge with new legislation is to embrace enduring normative principles without
codifying current economic learning in a way that will prevent the law from evolving to take
account of newer economic findings.
ii. Reform of Antitrust Law Through a General Tightening
As noted, most antitrust cases require uncertain decisions about unknowable future events like
innovation or entry or about unobservable economic elements like demand curves, marginal cost,
and product quality. Much US antitrust law reflects judgments about how to deal with such
uncertainty. Those judgments are embodied in rules regarding burdens of proof, evidentiary
presumptions, and decision-theoretic approaches to fact finding. They are also embodied in
substantive legal doctrine, such as rules regarding predatory pricing and unilateral refusals to
deal that are intended to reduce the likelihood of false positives (erroneously finding a business
has violated the law) even at the risk of false negatives (erroneously deciding that a business has
not violated the law). Digital markets typically have high levels of uncertainty and move quickly.
Given uncertainty, courts must determine how much weight to put on the risk of enforcement
mistakes: both the likelihood of a mistake and its cost. Much US antitrust law is driven by a
judgment, embraced by the Chicago School, that avoiding false positives (good conduct judged
to be bad) is more beneficial to society than avoiding false negatives (anticompetitive conduct
judged to be good).
151
This judgment rests on the beliefs that false positives are difficult to
correct but that false negatives will be quickly corrected by market forces. These beliefs seemed
149
As suggested, by, e.g., Elizabeth Warren, Here’s How We Can Break Up Big Tech, MEDIUM (Mar. 8, 2019),
https://medium.com/@teamwarren/heres-how-we-can-break-up-big-tech-9ad9e0da324c.
150
As suggested by, e.g., Elizabeth Warren, Leveling the Playing Field for America’s Family Farers, MEDIUM (Mar.
27, 2019), https://medium.com/@teamwarren/leveling-the-playing-field-for-americas-family-farmers-
823d1994f067.
151
For a classic statement of this proposition, see Frank H. Easterbrook, Vertical Arrangements and the Rule of
Reason, 53 A
NTITRUST L.J. 134, 135-36 (1984) (“There are limits on the ability of courts to sort the beneficial from
the deleterious manifestations of [restrictive dealing] practices, and most of the time it is better not to try than to try
and fail.”). For a criticism of this view, see Jonathan B. Baker, Taking the Error Out of ‘Error Cost’ Analysis:
What’s Wrong with Antitrust’s Right, 80 A
NTITRUST L.J. 1 (2015).
74
plausible in 1975 in a Chicago School framework, but they have never been empirically
demonstrated and have fallen into disrepute. Moreover, their logic is incomplete because the cost
to society of a false negative, for example, depends not only on its likelihood, but also on both
the magnitude and the duration of the resulting harm.
It is time for antitrust law to recalibrate the balance it strikes between the risks of false positives
and false negatives. Underenforcement is likely to be costlier than previously thought because,
among other things, market power of large technology platforms is more enduring. False
negatives are almost certainly more common than previously thought because certain types of
conduct that were previously thought to be benign are now understood to be anticompetitive.
Especially in technology markets, the most important competitive threats to incumbent firms are
likely to come from new entrants that might be vulnerable to exclusionary conduct or
anticompetitive acquisitions when their competitive prospects are uncertain. In addition, false
positives might be less common than previously thought because of the development in the past
few decades of more sophisticated and reliable econometric and simulation tools for assessing
conduct and market power effects. New work by economists studying multi-sided markets,
network effects, the economics of nominally “free” goods and services, and restrictive vertical
agreements suggests that antitrust agencies and courts will continue to improve in their ability to
make sound enforcement decisions. And false positives might be less costly than previously
thought because firms are finding new and different ways to realize efficiencies.
A recalibration of this type should influence antitrust law in two basic ways. First, it should
provide a basis for revising certain aspects of antitrust doctrine that were adopted explicitly in
order to minimize the risk of over-enforcement. Second, it could more broadly provide a basis
for courts to impose less demanding proof requirements on antitrust plaintiffs, especially where
facts are difficult to observe or prove directly and indirect or circumstantial proof is available.
Again, we pursue our theme of harm to entry through the next section. Exclusion of existing or
potential entrants is well established in both the economics literature and the antitrust
jurisprudence as a harm to competition, but the law is not well calibrated to recognize this
familiar tactic in its new setting.
Some of the specific ways in which the law might be revised are set forth below. They could be
achieved by common law-like evolution of antitrust law or by new legislation.
iii. Specific Areas of Possible Antitrust Reform [designed for the
specialist reader]
To address the issues raised by technology platforms, antitrust enforcement agencies and courts
will need to understand the unusual factual context that those platforms often present and be
receptive to recent and future economic learning about the implications of that context and how
to apply antitrust principles to it. Economists and other experts will need to develop new
75
understanding and new tools to aid agencies and courts in addressing these matters, among
others:
How to assess the quality-adjusted price paid for a good or service sold in a barter
transaction with zero or close to zero monetary price, and how to define and analyze
markets in which a substantial portion of the sale take the form of barter transactions.
How learning from behavioral economics and related disciplines about addictive or
exploitative content should be considered in addressing issues regarding economic
welfare.
How technology platforms are able to take advantage of consumer biases (such as
salience, status quo bias, or impatience) to bind consumers to their platforms and make
switching to alternatives more difficult than imagined by lay intuition (“competition is
one click away”).
152
How market circumstances affect the likelihood and nature of innovation and how to
evaluate innovation, whether using qualitative or quantitative tools, in both its magnitude
and direction.
How to assess potential competition from new or small firms or not-yet-identified future
innovators and entrants. This is especially important in markets that depend on
technological change and in which competition in the market is less important than leap-
frog competition for the market.
How to assess consumer welfare in a two-sided market. Learnings from platform
economics suggests that users on different sides of a platform generally have divergent
interests and thus that defining a single two‐sided marketrather than two, closely
interrelated onesobscures the analysis. Platform economics also demonstrates that
neither the change in the two sided price nor the change in the transaction volume is a
sufficient statistic for a how a firm’s conduct affects consumer welfare.
153
152
David Wismer, Google’s Larry Page: ‘Competition is One Click Away,’ (and Other Quotes of the Week),
F
ORBES (Oct. 14, 2012), https://www.forbes.com/sites/davidwismer/2012/10/14/googles-larry-page-competition-is-
one-click-away-and-other-quotes-of-the-week.
153
One of the features of such platforms is that, because of the feedback effects between the two sides of a platform
and the importance of the relative prices charged on the two sides, increased output by the platform does not
necessarily imply increased economic welfare. Whether increased output by the platform will increase economic
welfare depends on how the benefits and costs of that output are allocated across the two sides. See Michael L. Katz,
Platform Economics and Antitrust Enforcement: A Little Knowledge is a Dangerous Thing, 28 J.
ECON. & MGMT.
STRAT. 138 (2019); Jean-Charles Rochet & Jean Tirole, Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. EURO.
ECON. ASSOC. 990 (2003). There is another sense in which increased output of digital platforms does not necessarily
increase economic welfare. Because of some of the unique attributes of digital platforms discussed above, consumer
demand for digital services does not necessarily reflect consumer welfare from those services. See Section II.1,
76
Other antitrust reforms, including those below, would require changes to doctrine:
Antitrust law prohibits unilateral refusals to deal only under very unusual circumstances.
Current law reflects, among other things, concerns about the difficulty of determining the
required terms of trade and incentive effects of required dealing on both the dominant
firm and its rivals.
154
The law thus gives platforms substantial freedom both to refuse to
deal with actual or potential rivals, including complements, and to deal with them only on
onerous terms. Those terms might include access to customer data, interoperability, and
other terms that raise the costs of rivals and enable the platforms to reinforce their
dominant positions. This doctrine should be reconsidered in light of the substantial
importance of large technology platforms and, in particular, their central role as
distribution channels, both of which suggest that the benefits of antitrust intervention
might be greater than previously appreciated.
Predatory pricing law has been shaped in large part to avoid over-enforcement and with
explicit acknowledgement that the law permits some forms of anticompetitive pricing
conduct.
155
Courts have adopted a narrow and rigid notion of recoupment
156
and have
made it almost impossible to prove that prices are below cost, even where it seems
likely.
157
Digital goods often have a marginal cost close to zero, which makes tests that
require prices to be below incremental or variable cost almost impossible for a plaintiff to
meet. The law has also been construed to protect only rivals that are equally efficient at
the time of the conduct at issue and thus to disadvantage smaller rivals that have not yet
reached efficient scale. Predatory pricing law should be modified so that it will be better
able to combat anticompetitive pricing by digital platforms and other firms.
The paradigm of predatory pricing law has also been relied upon to assess more complex
pricing strategies, such as loyalty discounts. Loyalty discounts and similar contracts can
be used to drive one side of a platform to single-home, which can cause a market to tip
and enhance market power. The efficiency benefits of loyalty discounts are very different
from those of low prices in general; for example, unlike low prices themselves, even
above-cost loyalty discounts do not necessarily increase static welfare. Antitrust law
supra. This latter concern applies to other products as well, such as mortgages and prescription drugs; and it is very
relevant to possible regulation of digital platforms, as discussed below. By contrast, while antitrust enforcers and
courts need to understand those attributes of digital platforms in order to understand how the relevant markets work,
antitrust law is for several reasons based on the assumption that consumer preferences reflect consumer welfare.
154
See, e.g., Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (2004); see also A. Douglas
Melamed, Exclusionary Conduct Under the Antitrust Laws: Balancing, Sacrifice and Refusals to Deal, 20
B
ERKELEY TECH. J. 1247 (2006).
155
See Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227, 231, 234 (1st Cir. 1983) (Breyer, J.).
156
See C. Scott Hemphill & Philip J. Weiser, Beyond Brooke Group: Bringing Reality to the Law of Predatory
Pricing, 127 Y
ALE L.J. 2048 (2018).
157
See, e.g,, United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109 (10th Cir. 2003).
77
should not rely exclusively upon predatory pricing standards to assess loyalty
discounts.
158
The Supreme Court held in American Express that a plaintiff in a case involving a
vertical restraint must define and prove a relevant market and may not rely on direct
proof of harm to competition.
159
This holding was based on the notion that vertical
restraints almost always enhance efficiency and almost never harm competition. Scholars
over the past 30 years have demonstrated that that notion is false and therefore, that
vertical restraints must be evaluated individually on the specific facts.
160
Where there is
direct evidence of harm to competition, antitrust law should not require circumstantial
evidence via a defined relevant market.
Courts are generally very reluctant to second guess a defendant’s product design
decisions, even where the design harms competitors.
161
Yet product design decisions
involving, among other things, app stores, mobile device screen layouts, data storage and
analysis, and interface design are often key elements in digital market competition.
Antitrust courts should be more willing to assess product design decisions where
appropriate.
There should be no safe harbor based on the short-term of exclusive dealing agreements
and other restrictive vertical agreements when they are used by dominant platforms or
firms. Such firms can use their market power to induce desired behavior in trading
partners without relying on long-term contracts.
162
Perhaps most importantly, antitrust law might be revised to relax the proof requirements imposed
upon antitrust plaintiffs in appropriate cases or to reverse burdens of proof. Burdens of proof
might be switched by adopting rules that will presume anticompetitive harm on the basis of
preliminary showings by antitrust plaintiffs and shift a burden of exculpation to the defendant or
by ensuring that plaintiffs are not required to prove matters to which the defendants have greater
knowledge and better access to relevant information. These proof requirements include the
following, which are likely to be important in the application of antitrust standards to technology
platforms:
158
See Hemphill & Weiser, supra note 156.
159
Ohio v. American Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018).
160
See Steven C. Salop, Revising the Vertical Merger Guidelines: Presentation at the FTC Hearings on Competition
and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century (Nov. 1, 2018),
https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_events/1415284/ftc_hearings_5_georgetown_slides.pdf; Steven
C. Salop, Invigorating Vertical Merger Enforcement, 127 Y
ALE L.J. 1742 (2018).
161
See United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (per curiam).
162
Compare United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181 (3d Cir. 2005), with Omega Envtl., Inc. v. Gilbarco,
Inc., 127 F.3d 1157 (9th Cir. 1997).
78
Mergers between dominant firms and substantial competitors or uniquely likely future
competitors should be presumed to be unlawful, subject to rebuttal by defendants. This
presumption would be valuable, not because it would identify anticompetitive mergers
with precision, but because it would shift the burden to the party with the best access to
relevant information on issues of competitive effects and efficiencies from the merger.
Courts should not presume efficiencies from vertical transactions. Crediting of
efficiencies should require strong supporting evidence showing merger-specificity and
verifiability.
163
Courts should be more willing to permit plaintiffs to prove harm to competition by
circumstantial evidence, especially where the propositions in question are not observable
and there thus cannot be direct evidence.
164
iv. A Competition Court
Revisions to the law may have little effect to the extent that judges see antitrust cases only rarely
and have difficulty understanding the economic underpinning of antitrust law. One way to
ameliorate this problem would be to establish a specialized antitrust court on which a certain
number of Article III judges would sit for a specified term of several years. These judges could
be expected to hear multiple antitrust cases and to develop substantial antitrust expertise. And,
because they would be chosen from the general federal bench, they would bring the broader
perspective of generalist judges. This model could be used at the trial court level, the appellate
level, or both. If judges are selected from the larger pool of Article III judges and rotated on and
off the specialized court, judges on the specialized court will be less likely to develop an overly
narrow intellectual interpretation of antitrust law.
v. A Regulatory Partner Could Enhance Effective Antitrust
Enforcement
Digital markets move quickly. Using the internet as a distribution channel to reach an installed
base of billions around the globe means that new products can be rolled out quickly—as can
anticompetitive conduct. The pace of antitrust enforcement is far slower—judging by the
evidence, too slow—to protect small entrants except by creating deterrence. A sectoral regulator,
by contrast, could be endowed with the authority to move quickly. By taking steps to preserve
competition before markets have tipped or entrants have been purchased, a regulator could prove
a valuable complement to antitrust enforcement.
163
For an example of the Court presuming efficiencies from vertical transactions with minimal evidence, see
American Express, 138 S. Ct. at 2289.
164
See, e.g., id. (injury to competition in a two-sided market); United States v. AMR Corp., 335 F.3d 1109 (10th Cir.
2003) (predatory pricing).
79
Antitrust enforcement proceeds on a case-by-case basis, and, apart from merger enforcement, it
is largely backward looking—it looks at conduct already undertaken that is alleged to harm
competition. A regulator, by contrast, can look forward and establish rules to constrain future
conduct before there has been harm to competition, or before investments by the defendant and
third parties have been shaped by the conduct. This is particularly useful in cases where ex post
conduct remedies would be costly or ineffective.
Effective antitrust enforcement requires effective remedies. Treble damages and financial
penalties can compensate for past harms and deter future bad conduct, but they do not restore
competition to markets in which competition has been harmed. Even an injunction to forbear
from the same or similar anticompetitive conduct going forward will not restore the lost
competition if entry barriers are high. For example, if the market has tipped and network
externalities are very strong, the firm that became a monopolist through violations of the antitrust
laws could stop the conduct at issue and yet retain its monopoly position and the associated
stream of profits. An antitrust authority that wants to restore lost competition must induce entry
and/or impose structural remedies. Such remedies are likely to require detailed and often
technical monitoring and years of effort. Antitrust enforcers are not suited to that type of
oversight whereas a sectoral regulator is. One possible solution is to permit antitrust authorities
and courts to design antitrust remedies and rely on an expert sectoral regulator to oversee their
implementation. A similar approach was approved by the Supreme Court in the Otter Tail
case.
165
e. Regulation
For the reasons above, we believe the establishment of a sectoral regulator should be seriously
considered. Given the tasks detailed by the other committees in this project as well as this one,
there would be much for a regulator to do that would improve the impact of digital platforms on
society. A digital regulator, should Congress choose to create one, could consider regulations and
actions along the following lines. We call this potential regulator the Digital Authority (DA).
The general harm identified above is insufficient entry, and therefore insufficient competition, in
digital platforms. Many of the regulations below are designed to lower barriers to entry directly.
Others are responsive to the difficulty of effectively prosecuting antitrust cases today in digital
markets. Regulations that mimic the antitrust laws but lower the burden of proof for the regulator
and allow it to move faster are a way to gain effective enforcement in this sector, if not others.
Regulation offers a valuable addition to antitrust enforcement. It can help design the digital
landscape and align the interests and incentives of platforms and key providers with those of
consumers and society. When carefully designed, a regulatory regime can limit or even preempt
the harmful effects detailed above, while minimizing its impact on the dynamic nature of digital
165
Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366 (1973).
80
markets. It can offer clarity and legal certainty as to the boundaries of acceptable competition.
Moreover, some of the problems discussed above may have only one structural solution: breakup
of the platform. An enforcer might not want to choose that option because it is very disruptive.
But less disruptive ex post remedies require ongoing monitoring, which antitrust enforcers are
not well-positioned to do. Handing that job off to a regulator might better serve consumers.
Therefore, the committee suggests considering regulatory steps in conjunction with improved
antitrust enforcement. It is important that regulation support, and indeed enhance, competition.
The report focuses here on regulations targeted at improving competition, not other policy
challenges related to digital platforms. And it is critical that any new regulatory framework avoid
the well-documented pitfalls that regulation often invites (e.g., agency capture, revolving door
syndrome, or incumbent protection). By having a pro-competition mandate, our hope is that the
DA will be able to use the tools at its disposal in ways that resist the natural impediments to
entry identified in Part I, rather than entrench powerful incumbents.
This combination of enforcement tools applied to one industry is nothing new in the US
economy. Virtually every sector of our economy has required both antitrust and specific
regulatory oversight, from banking to agriculture to communications, in order to promote
competition and other public interest goals. The regulations we propose below are focused on,
and limited to, those that will enhance competition.
The communications sector may offer the best guidance for how to approach public
accountability for digital platforms. Telephone, cable, and wireless communications networks
have many of the same attributes as digital platforms. Large capital expenditures to build
networks, declining costs as consumers use the networks and buy more services on the networks,
and the difficulties for new players to enter these markets and compete have led to a world of one
or few players in each market. And just like social networking, online search, and web-delivered
content, communications networks have been the lifeblood of how we communicate and practice
our democracy by delivering TV, radio, text, and conversation, making competitive outcomes in
the sector critical. The FCC has served as the sector-specific regulator for telecommunications.
In complex industries, a sector-specific regulator can have a wider remit than an antitrust
authority as is detailed in the box below.
81
Box VI
The FCC Model
In the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Congress sought to affirmatively promote, not just
protect, competition.
1
Congress’ vision included service availability that was universal and
affordable to all and a commitment to local and diverse ownership of news sources to support
a robust marketplace of ideas.
2
It wanted to prevent undue discrimination, limit ownership to
prevent excess market power (both horizontally and vertically in some instances), and police
against abusive contract provisions that distort fair market practices.
3
Some of these goals
were achieved with more success than others. And in general, the regulatory process
inherently restricts behavior and therefore efficiencies. The net benefits of regulation should
factor in these lost efficiencies.
The phone number portability rule was a clearly pro-competitive regulation. The FCC
published the Wireless Local Number Portability rule in 2003.
4
The rule allows cell phone
users to keep their phone number when they switch between wireless carriers. Prior to the
rule, a consumer who wanted to take advantage of a low price or better quality with a
competing provider would have had to change her phone number. This significant switching
cost dampened competition between carriers. The number portability rule made switching
easier and thereby strengthened competition between carriers.
5
Similarly, when portability of
1-800 numbers (e.g., 1-800-flowers) was introduced, prices of those services fell.
6
After Congress found the cable companies to be local monopolies in 1992, Congress
identified a dearth in cable competition partially caused by vertically-integrated cable
operators’ refusal to sell their programming to potential competitors. It therefore temporarily
prohibited exclusive programming contracts, banned a variety of abusive contracting
practices, and required that vertically-integrated firms sell their content to competitors under
reasonable prices, terms, and conditions.
7
1 H.R. Rep. No. 104-458 (1996) (Conf. Rep.). Even before the 1996 Act, the FCC had already begun the work
of promoting competition through the broad authority it had been granted in earlier statutes.
2 47 U.S.C. § 151 (2018).
3 Id.; 47 U.S.C. § 160 (2018).
4 See generally Wireless Local Number Portability (WLNP), F
ED. TRADE COMMN,
https://www.fcc.gov/general/wireless-local-number-portability-wlnp.
5 Press Release, Federal Communications Commission, FCC Observes First Anniversary of Wireless Local
Number Portability (Nov. 24, 2004), https://www.fcc.gov/document/fcc-observes-first-anniversary-wireless-
local-number-portability (“Wireless local number portability (LNP) eliminated a barrier to full competition in
mobile telephone services and between landline and wireless services”).
6 V. Brian Viard, Do Switching Costs Make Markets More or Less Competitive? The Case of 800-Number
Portability (Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business Research Paper No. 1773R2, 2004),
https://ssrn.com/abstract=371921
.
7 47 U.S.C. § 251 (2018).
82
The FCC Model (Cont.)
The resulting increased competition in the cable industry enabled the Direct Broadcasting
Satellite industry to grow,
1
opened the door for telephone companies and smaller cable
providers to compete in the provision of distribution,
2
and ultimately drove the digital video
market to develop today’s cable-modem-powered broadband internet services.
The 1996 Telecommunications Act included interconnection requirements between
competing carriers to expand competition. The Act outlined a regulatory regime of duties to
connect, of parity in quality between connections offered to the incumbent’s own affiliates
and competitors, and of rates and contract terms that were just, reasonable, and
nondiscriminatory.
3
The regulation was designed to protect all of the businesses that needed
to connect to the long-distance wire for their business but competed with a vertically-
integrated local wire. Not only was raising rivals’ costs prohibited, but complete foreclosure
was also prohibited. This duty to deal in a non-discriminatory way is an example of a policy
that arguably promoted entry of cable, local telephone, and long-distance competitors.
Similarly, the FCC developed Customer Proprietary Network Information (CPNI) rules,
designed to protect sensitive business data transmitted through public telecommunications
networks. The FCC recognized that a dominant platform, such as the telephone company, on
which businesses rely in order to reach their customers, could easily gather and take
advantage of sensitive business user data to promote the phone company’s business and harm
competition.
4
Phone service competitors, as well as data-driven businesses (such as home-
security monitoring firms, hotels, and airlines), rely upon these rules to grow their businesses
without interference from telecom network owners. The rule was so effective at promoting
competition that Congress codified it in the 1996 Telecommunications Act. The harvesting of
data flowing through a platform—generated by and belonging to others—is a standard
business practice among today’s digital platforms.
Of course, these past regulatory efforts have also helped us learn what not to do. Regulations
could be and have been used to entrench incumbent firms’ market power, erecting regulatory
barriers to entry for new or innovative competitors.
1 47 U.S.C. § 548(a) (2018).
2 47 U.S.C. § 521(6) (2018); 47 U.S.C. § 548 (2018).
3 47 U.S.C. § 251 (2018).
4 47 U.S.C. § 222 (2018).
83
i. The Digital Authority
To be effective, a proposed regulatory regime requires an enforcement body capable of carefully
designing and enforcing the relevant regulations. We start therefore with a proposal for Congress
to pass legislation creating a Digital Authority with the mandate to develop targeted regulation to
achieve the goals described above and subsequently engage in monitoring and enforcement.
We anticipate that this regulator will also be tasked with non-competition digital goals, such as
those in the areas of privacy, media, data-use restrictions, and consumer protection. While the
antitrust agencies will employ structural interventions to protect competitive markets wherever
possible, the focus of this regulator will be on both carrying out remedies for the antitrust
authority that require ongoing oversight, and on developing regulations going forward that are a
combination of structural safeguards, such as unbundling or separation, with limited behavioral
interventions in areas where traditional antitrust tools are insufficient. Other jurisdictions that are
The FCC Model (Cont.)
Regulatory capture is a common problem.
1
For example, AT&T has historically had a
symbiotic relationship with the US government.
2
Perhaps the height of this relationship was
the explicit Kingsbury Commitment in 1913, which allowed AT&T, rather than the
government, to set the “solution” for managing competition.
3
The current Chairman of the
FCC, Ajit Pai, has called this “a cautionary tale about the dangers of regulatory capture.”
4
It
was likely this close relationship that allowed the AT&T monopoly to persist for so long,
eventually requiring an antitrust case to address the problem.
1 See George J. Stigler, The Theory of Economic Regulation, 2 BELL J. ECON. REG. 3 (1971) (arguing that, as a
rule, regulation is acquired by the industry and is designed and operated primarily for its benefit.”); see also
Sheldon Whitehouse, Legal Responses to Regulatory Capture, ACS
BLOG (Nov. 9, 2018),
https://www.acslaw.org/acsblog/blog-post-for-the-american-constitution-society-legal-responses-to-regulatory-
capture (“We unfortunately live in a time of widespread regulatory capture. We should not pretend otherwise.”);
Elizabeth Warren, Corporate Capture of the Rulemaking Process, REG. REV
. (June 14, 2016),
https://www.theregreview.org/2016/06/14/warren-corporate-capture-of-the-rulemaking-process (“Under the law,
it is easy for business groups to challenge a rule for being too strong or too restrictive. But it is much harder for
public interest groups or ordinary citizens to challenge a rule for being too weak or riddled with loopholes.”);
Daniel Carpenter, Challenges in Measuring Regulatory Capture, REG. REV.
(June 22, 2016),
https://www.theregreview.org/2016/06/22/carpenter-challenges-measuring-regulatory-capture (
“[T]here are
limitations when it comes to preventing capture. Perhaps the most important is that capture is difficult to
measure”).
2 Chris Matthews, AT&T and the Government Have Been ‘Friends’ for a Really Long Time, FORTUNE (Aug. 18,
2015), http://fortune.com/2015/08/18/att-nsa.
3 Ajit Pai, Chairman, Fed. Commc’n Comm’n, Remarks on the 100
th
Anniversary of the Kingsburgy Commitment
(Dec. 19, 2013), https://www.fcc.gov/document/pai-remarks-100th-anniversary-kingsbury-commitment.
4 Id.
84
assessing competition in digital platforms all propose some form of regulation.
166
Having
forward-looking regulations in place will increase business certainty about what conduct is
permitted and how enforcement actions are likely to proceed. Ideally, this predictability and
clarity will encourage companies to comply with the law, thus requiring fewer government
resources for enforcement.
The DA legislation will require Congress to define the scope of regulatory power. The definition
must include digital businesses that facilitate transactions of any kind (including the sale of
advertising). It should have clear and broad authority over digital business models in order to
prevent firms subject to regulation from evading its oversight.
We offer a menu of potential regulation, starting with the least intrusive form and building to the
more severe interventions. Each type of regulation comes with costs and benefits which we
briefly detail. The size of the costs and benefits will be different across settings, meaning that the
choice of the best tool for any particular case may vary. The committee also suggests separating
out some types of regulation that will apply to virtually all market participants while others are
only appropriate tools to apply to companies with bottleneck power.
1) Bottleneck power
“Bottleneck power” describes a situation where consumers primarily single-home and rely upon
a single service provider (a “bottleneck”), which makes obtaining access to those consumers for
the relevant activity by other service providers prohibitively costly. As the U.K. Furman Report
put it,
[O]ne, or in some cases two firms in certain digital markets have a high degree of control
and influence over the relationship between buyers and sellers, or over access by
advertisers to potential buyers. As these markets are frequently important routes to
market, or gateways for other firms, such bottlenecks are then able to act as a gatekeeper
between businesses and their prospective customers.
167
The finding of bottleneck power will employ consideration of the forces that, as discussed above
in this Report, tend to impede entry and lead to foreclosure. The Furman Report similarly
explains that this single-homing foreclosure tends to happen when users experience high
switching costs, such as loss of valued personal data or reputational indicators at the point of
switching; contract terms that deter switching; technical barriers to switching, such as complex
switching processes or a lack of interoperability between the old service and the new or second
service; tying services, which can be by contract or technical; and the inertia of defaults.
168
166
See, e.g., AUSTRALIAN COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 13-14; EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at
8-10; U.K. C
OMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 60-61.
167
U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 41.
168
Id. at 36.
85
Digital businesses that have this incentive and ability to develop and preserve a single-homing
environment should be considered entities with bottleneck power. The DA, pursuant to
congressional guidance, should have the sole authority to define bottleneck power and should
update the definition either regularly or on an “as needed” basis. This is not a determination that
should be left for definition by generalist judges. If Congress establishes a specialized panel of
judges who review antitrust matters (as described above), it would be wise to grant the same
panel sole judicial review authority over DA regulatory actions.
2) Data
Should Congress pass any laws concerning consumer data, the authority could set forth pro-
competitive rules concerning the consequences of consumers’ control over their data and about
user choice in the sharing of data. Where users are simply and clearly informed and given the
opportunity to make viable choices about which companies get their data, this valuable
competitive information can be shared as the consumer prefers. The DA could design data
sharing rules with the general goal of reducing single-homing and promoting entry.
3) Partnership with the Antitrust Agencies
Antitrust enforcement agencies or courts could designate the DA as the administrator and/or
architect of remedies in antitrust cases. In cases where structural remedies are not appropriate to
restore the lost competition, the DA could be directed to either carry out a remedy designed by
the competition authority, or provide an effective behavioral monitoring remedy consistent with
the DA’s mandate. Since the difficulty of designing an appropriate and administrable antitrust
remedy that can be enforced by a court often limits antitrust enforcement, having the option of an
expert regulator to craft the remedy, or to simply be responsible for ongoing monitoring or other
execution of the remedy, could better ensure cost-effective enforcement of pro-competition
policies.
The DA can partner with the antitrust agency when it observes anticompetitive conduct. Due to
their frequent interaction with firms in the industry and their real-time data feed, regulators may
observe exclusionary conduct before the antitrust authority, and be able to give it relevant
information and data.
ii. Menu of Regulations
We lay out below a menu of regulations that could be used to solve the problems identified
above from least interventionist to most interventionist. For each, we describe the likely benefits
and the costs.
86
1) Broadly Applicable Regulations
Some of these regulatory tools should be applied broadly to all firms in the industry, not only to
bottleneck firms. It would be appropriate, however, to include a small business exception and
perhaps even a new business exception, to allow very small entrants, who may benefit
competition, time to ramp up against larger established companies.
a. Data collection
The Digital Authority could regularly collect data on market transactions, with an emphasis on
data from businesses with bottleneck power. The information would allow policy makers and
researchers to assess the performance of the sector and improve rule enforcement. For example,
the data may include, inter alia, a sample of searches at a set of websites, a sample of queries
followed by purchases at other sites, a sample of downloads of applications at an app store, or a
sample of activity and ads shown on a social media site. The DA may further regularly collect
information, including what types of data the business collects, how it uses that data, and who
else is bartered or sold access to which elements of the data. It may include experiments to
evaluate the true portability of data, the ads generated by certain user information, and other
information relevant to assessing how and if competition is taking hold in the market. This
program will require ongoing costs to run, but these should be reasonable compared to the
benefits.
Box VII
Real Time Regulation in Financial Services
Technological innovation and the data revolution are also disrupting the financial services
market, spurring regulators into action. Banks and other companies are undergoing an
innovation and digitization spree, partially in response to competition by non-financial
institutions and startups. This rapid change increases the challenges for regulators to follow
and analyze what regulated companies are doing.
The response by some financial regulators has been to embrace new technologies focused on
machine readable regulation (with the help of machine learning and AI) and digital reporting
(with the help of data sharing frameworks, APIs, cloud computing, and advanced analytics).
This is leading to an important shift from manual and template driven compliance and
regulatory reporting to a near real time or real time regulatory reporting and supervision.
Examples of authorities adopting this system range from the European Central Bank, various
national central banks in continental Europe, the Monetary Authority of Singapore, or more
notably, the Bank of England and the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA) in the UK.
87
These data may be requested by an antitrust agency to aid in an investigation or prosecution.
This ability to transfer existing data will speed up the enforcement of antitrust laws. After an
investigation is opened, rather than subpoenaing the relevant data from the targeted firms and
spending months arguing over definitions and formats, the antitrust authority could immediately
begin analysis with the DA dataset.
In addition, the DA should make as much of these data public as possible, subject to keeping
personally identifiable information and business secrets confidential. This will allow academics
and nonprofits to study particular markets and consumer behavior as they do in industries such as
airlines (where “Data Bank 1A” is publicly available)
169
to great public benefit. Leveraging the
nonprofit and educational sector to help the DA and elected officials understand these markets is
likely to be helpful and cost-effective.
b. Restrictions on Practices That Enhance Behavioral “Mistakes”
As described above, it is well known that behavioral “nudges” can lead consumers to make better
choices. Better choices promote competition because they generate increased market share for
firms that make better offers to consumers. The DA should have a mandate to create such “light
touch” rules when they will make markets more competitive. For example, automatic renewals
can discourage consumers from comparison shopping when a contract ends. A restriction on
automatic renewals in that setting could lower prices market-wide. Regulations that require firms
to make salient the most important terms of an offer can improve competition (e.g., a credit card
offer must show the APR in large font). The U.K. likely has the most advanced regulatory
169
See Bureau Transportation Stat., Sources of Aviation Data, U.S. DEPT TRANSPORTATION (2017),
https://www.bts.gov/explore-topics-and-geography/topics/sources-aviation-data.
Real Time Regulation in Financial Services (Cont.)
The Bank of England and the FCA are arguably the most advanced when it comes to digital
regulatory reporting. Both were the first financial regulators to set up innovation labs and
programs to interact with startups and new technologies. Their aim is to assess which regulation
is suitable for machine reading, what data could be included in a standardized fashion within a
digital regulatory reporting framework and how these changes will impact data models currently
used for regulatory stress testing, leading to upgrades. This standardization then allows for near
real time data sharing, lowering compliance costs to small and big firms alike.
Closer to home, in the United States, the SEC is implementing rules requiring trading firms to
report intra-day trading data in real time. The SEC, the CFTC and the FDIC have also each set
up fintech/regtech innovation labs to assess fintech solutions in general and regulatory tech
solutions in particular. A Digital Authority could learn from, and expand on, these experiences
of near real time regulation when overseeing an industry that has data at its core.
88
regime in this regard, and the DA may be able to learn from it and other jurisdictions that have
already taken these steps.
170
c. Data Portability and Mobility
Congress may, at some point, pass a data law of some type that gives consumers control of their
data. For this control to translate into more competitive markets, it must be used to lower
switching costs and facilitate entry. The DA has a role to ensure that users can easily transfer
their data from one service to another in industries where there is a common business model
(e.g., social media, banking, or online grocery shopping). The DA will identify industries where
porting is likely to aid the competitive process. Being able to port one’s data directly lowers the
cost of moving from one service to another, which in turn causes businesses to compete harder to
keep those customers.
171
Consumers who control their data and have the right to receive it in a
standardized format from the business will be able to take advantage of a new entrant by porting
themselves to it, along with their own data. With information about a user’s past purchases, likes,
friends, and so forth, the entrant can provide a higher-quality service and grow more quickly.
The DA could propose a standard for exchanging the data, but remain open to options that
industry favors, provided the format is not itself an entry barrier. The data porting standard
should be updated frequently to accommodate new innovations in the industry. New innovators
can think broadly about what services users might like that rely on this data, or are compensated
through access to the data.
172
The Vestager Report divides data into personal and not personal;
and content into volunteered, observed, and inferred.
173
The DA could determine which of these
types of data must be included in the portability standard.
While a porting regulation lowers consumer switching costs greatly, they may still be high
enough that demand is not sufficiently contestable to induce entry.
174
The DA could also set up a
process by which a customer can choose to send her data to an entrant by authorizing it to be
transferred directly from her former service provider. The DA would need to authorize the
entrant to offer this facility to its consumers and establish regulations to require the incumbent to
transfer the consumer’s data upon the authorized request from the entrant. This may be
particularly useful as the Internet of Things becomes more important; a consumer may wish to
170
See Fletcher, supra note 47.
171
This is why incumbents may create or maintain systems that make data portability difficult. See Section I.1.B.1,
supra.
172
See, e.g., the RadicalxChange group. Mission and Values, RADICALXCHANGE (2019),
https://radicalxchange.org/about/. The group’s chair, Glen Weyl, has argued in a paper written with colleagues that
it’s a mistake to view internet services priced at $0 as simply free; instead, data can be viewed as a form of labor or
barter. See Imanol Arrieta-Ibarra et al., Should We Treat Data as Labor? Moving Beyond “Free”, 108 A
MER. ECON.
ASSOC. PAPERS & PROCEEDINGS 38 (2018), https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/pandp.20181003
(exploring “whether and how treating the market for data like a labor market could serve as a radical market that is
practical in the near term”).
173
See EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 8; id. at 24.
174
See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 129, § 5.11.
89
port the food supply service that was bundled with her new refrigerator from Amazon to an
entrant. Being able to authorize the entrant to obtain all her data from Amazon will lower the
cost of switching. Conceptually, automatic porting is no different from manual porting, but it is
mechanized in a way that is likely to raise contestability and therefore can make entry more
profitable. The Vestager Report notes that the GDPR Article 20 provides these data portability
rights to Europeans. If consumers have the right to quickly and easily patronize an entrant
without data lock-in, there will be more incentive to enter into these markets. However, other
entry barriers remain, which we discuss below.
d. Open Standards to Promote Competition
The DA should move preemptively to prevent the consolidation of control over users’ identities,
as this would create a large new source of market power. The DA could create an open standard
so that new entrants can easily offer their own digital identity product that allows users to access
goods and services online. One example of this type of product is Solid, by Tim Berners-Lee,
often named as the creator of the World Wide Web. Solid offers users a “POD” that safeguards
their digital identity that they can use to connect with different services.
175
Several government-
backed efforts at identity portability are underway across the world. These include Estonia’s e-
Estonia initiative to give citizens a unique digital identifier; India’s Aadhaar, a verifiable 12-digit
identity number issued for each citizen which serves as an identifier and authenticator for a
variety of offline and online services; Sweden’s and Norway’s BankId, which allows companies,
banks, and governmental agencies to identify and conclude agreements with individuals over the
internet; and even self-sovereign identity solutions studied by start-ups that would use
blockchain to allow individuals to own their identity credentials and control who can access their
data in online services. If an individual could then port their identity to the platforms and
providers they wish to use, this would again promote entry of new services and erode the
switching costs of established platforms.
The DA could consider creating an open standard that would facilitate micro-payments among
consumers and digital entities. The coordination needed among stakeholders to create a
successful micro-payment system is substantial, and it likely will require assistance and
oversight from a regulator.
e. Merger Review
The behavior that may be of greatest concern to the many policymakers studying powerful
digital businesses is their acquisition of potential competitors. These acquisitions often fall below
the value threshold under which the buyer would need to notify competition authorities in
advance of the deal. As a consequence, authorities have limited or no ability to assess whether a
175
See How It Works, SOLID (2019), https://solid.inrupt.com/how-it-works.
90
given deal is procompetitive or harmful to competition before it closes.
176
Markets move quickly
and a competitor’s window of opportunity to gain traction against the incumbent is short. For
these reasons, Congress could give the DA merger review authority. Similar to the FCC’s merger
review role, this would be conducted concurrently with the antitrust review done by the FTC or
DOJ, but with different standards and tools. It would not be prudent to alter the nation’s antitrust
laws to accommodate one difficult and fast-moving sector where false negatives are particularly
costly. Therefore, giving additional power over merger review to the sectoral regulator is a good
solution.
These specific merger regulations should require merging firms to demonstrate that the
combination will affirmatively promote competition. This shifting of the burden of proof from
the government (to prove harm) to the parties (to prove benefit) will assist the DA by placing the
job of demonstrating efficiencies on the parties, who have a greater ability to know what they
are. In some cases, the DA’s review may be the only merger review conducted, as it should not
be subject to the minimum size limitations on HSR filings. In particular, notification and pre-
clearance could be required for any acquisition by a business designated as having bottleneck
power.
177
In its merger review process, the DA could be explicitly tasked with evaluating a given merger’s
likely harm to existing as well as potential competition. Another example discussed above is the
case of content or complements that could expand from that position to compete with the digital
bottleneck business itself. As already noted, entry from elsewhere in the vertical (or
conglomerate) chain may be the most effective and promising entry point to challenge an
established bottleneck business. Mergers with either of these types of entrants have the effect of
neutralizing companies that might one day have posed a competitive challenge to the bottleneck
business. This view of potential competition should drive DA merger review.
The decision in Credit Suisse and the dicta, or language, in Trinko greatly expanded the
industries and conduct that have become, for practical purposes, exempt from antitrust
scrutiny.
178
The agencies have understandably been skittish to expend limited resources bringing
cases that risk being thrown out on Trinko grounds.
179
It is important that Trinko not be used to
176
See Section III.2.B, supra, for a further discussion of these difficulties.
177
When network effects are strong, a digital business with bottleneck power will likely only have very small
competitors. Therefore, even small transactions can neutralize an important potential competitor that is poised to
grow. See Section III.3.B, supra.
178
See Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC v. Billing, 551 U.S. 264 (2007); Verizon Communications v. Law
Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398 (2004).
179
Howard Shelanski, at the time the FTC’s top antitrust economist, testified in Congress on behalf of the
Commission a few years after the Credit Suisse decision. He argued that a narrow interpretation of Trinko was
possible. See Is There Life After Trinko and Credit Suisse? The Role of Antitrust in Regulated Industries: Hearing
Before the Subcomm. on Courts and Competition Policy of the H. Comm. of the Judiciary, 111th Cong. (2010)
(statement of Howard Shelanski, Deputy Director for Antitrust in the Bureau of Economics at the FTC),
https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/prepared-statement-federal-trade-commission-
courts-and-competition-policy-committee-judiciary-united/100615antitrusttestimony.pdf [hereinafter Shelanksi
91
create a no-man’s land where neither regulation nor antitrust are applied to harmful behavior. A
traditional antitrust savings clause can no longer be relied upon, as the clause in the 1996
Telecom Act was found insufficient to protect antitrust enforcement in Trinko. Legislation
creating regulation and antitrust enforcement for digital businesses should address this concern
head on. The statute must be extremely specific, explaining for each tool and goal whether it is
intended to supersede antitrust or not. Antitrust enforcers and other agencies can share dual
authority with different review standards and goals. They can account for each other's
determinations in a manner that will minimize inconsistencies without having one always take
priority over the other. Antitrust must remain in full force except where Congress explicitly says
otherwise.
The merger review process must move rapidly. The agency will need a simple and efficient
merger review process so that businesses can move forward without undue delay, and the agency
does not expend more resources than necessary. These concerns indicate that the burden of proof
must primarily be placed on the merging parties who have the incentive, data, and resources to
quickly deliver the right information to the authority. Decisions should be subject to judicial
review, like a rulemaking process under the Administrative Procedure Act, with reliance on the
specialist Competition Court discussed above. However, in light of the difficulty of winning
antitrust cases in current US courts, judicial review will be effective at supporting the mission of
the DA when combined with a more explicit and tougher enforcement statute or a Competition
Court, or both.
In order for the agency to be most efficient, it should use a combination of adjudication and
rulemaking for these merger transaction reviews. Rules help businesses know what behavior is
proscribed, and help the agency clarify its intentions without having to wait for a good test
caseor multiple test cases—to fully explain the issue. Clear rules will help companies avoid
proposing anticompetitive transactions to begin with.
The cost of such regulation is duplicative merger reviews. However, given the importance of
markets that tip and the uncertainty about whether an acquisition is a substitute or complement,
having two reviews is perhaps helpful in getting to the right answer. If the regulator can block an
incumbent platform’s acquisition of potential competitors, and those competitors have the ability
to quickly get their customers’ data, entrants will plan to enter and compete with the platform,
rather than enter and be bought. If the competitive environment is improved by data portability
Testimony]. The key facts in Trinko were that the legislation at issue, the 1996 Telecom Act, went farther than
antitrust law; an agency, the FCC, had issued rules directly regulating the conduct at issue; and the FCC actively
administered those rules. See Trinko, 540 U.S. 398. Shelanski argued that “[w]here a competent agency actively
administers a rule whose standard for the competitive conduct at issue in litigation is more demanding on the
defendant than antitrust law, the Court was right to find it relevant whether the marginal gains outweigh the potential
costs of antitrust enforcement against the same conduct.” Shelanski Testimony at 9. Yet he expressed concern that
courts may use much broader interpretations of the line of cases. The Court in Trinko expressed concern about
misuse of antitrust law by impudent plaintiffs, so some preemption could be limited to private plaintiffs, with expert
agencies being given greater leeway.
92
and the elimination of exclusionary conduct, the chance of success will rise and consumers will
benefit from increased competition.
f. Interoperability
There may be settings where the DA is charged by Congress to prevent the creation of market
power in the first place due to the importance of the market and the potential harms from the
market power. Such a market would be a candidate for open interoperability standards that could
be used by all competitors and would promote entry. The DA could oversee the creation of an
open standard and its adoption in the market of interest. For example, devices in the home might
be required to adhere to an open standard so that any platform could connect with any device.
Without such a standard, an Apple thermostat would not function in conjunction with a Google
home assistant. Under an open standard, if a consumer had purchased a number of Amazon
appliances and then switched her home assistant from Amazon to Apple, she would not need to
purchase a new refrigerator, thermostat, and security system because all of those devices could
connect to the new platform and stay functional. It is possible that such open standards can slow
down innovation that depends on the interface, but open standards will drastically reduce lock-in
and market power, leading to greater incentive to innovate on the service itself.
2) Regulations that apply to firms with bottleneck power
Some regulations should apply only to firms that meet the DA’s definition for bottleneck power.
In these cases, the bottleneck firm has the incentive and ability to harm competition and is an
important source of consumer welfare. These firms require extra monitoring to be sure they are
not violating antitrust, or other laws, because of the uncertainties in technology and demand, the
speed at which platforms tip, the irreversibility of tipping, and the need for expert evaluation of
the design of algorithms. For all of these reasons, the cost of false negatives is high and
therefore, under conditions of uncertainty, the public interest requires the DA to take a more
interventionist approach.
180
a. Mergers
The DA could be given merger review authority over all transactions involving digital businesses
with bottleneck power because new competition against these entities is the most valuable for
consumers. Businesses with bottleneck power would notify the DA and obtain pre-clearance for
an acquisition of any size. While this would potentially result in many reviews for the DA, their
number will be limited by the number of platforms with bottleneck power.
The DA may want to use its merger review authority over bottleneck firms to assess
consummated mergers, just as the antitrust authority can under section 7 of the Clayton Act. Past
180
If these regulations fail to create or maintain competitive digital markets, the DA should alert Congress that
neither antitrust nor existing regulatory tools are effective so that Congress may consider stronger steps.
93
mergers of potential competitors that created monopoly positions could be assessed in this way.
Similarly, past vertical mergers (e.g. a business that develops tools for brands to place ads and a
business that runs mechanisms to set ad prices) may be found to cause higher prices or otherwise
lessen competition. Any such anticompetitive mergers could be unwound by the DA.
b. Non-discrimination and foreclosure
Discrimination against current or future rivals is an important tool in a foreclosure strategy by a
digital business with bottleneck market power.
181
As explained above, there are broadly two
types of foreclosure of a complement: one that operates against a complement that is a potential
competitor of the platform itself, and one that operates only on the platform between rival
providers of content. Because large digital platforms today are conglomerates with large eco-
systems of complements, this is an important area in which to enforce competition. Non-
discrimination can be a helpful tool in creating a competitive environment in which entrants are
protected and can thrive, while allowing a platform to vertically integrate to some degree. Non-
discrimination requirements should be used only after careful study because they can also
prevent efficient forms of service that enhance competition.
Anticompetitive foreclosure of a firm that is a current or potential competitor can be addressed
by the antitrust authority if the antitrust law is strong enough. If not, there will be a role for the
DA to develop a stronger rule in order to successfully enforce against such foreclosure by firms
with bottleneck power. Furthermore, the DA could use similar rules in a forward-looking
regulatory context. Effective non-discrimination rules can foster entry and diversity, create
potential sources of disruptive innovation and protect start-ups and other entrants. The goal of
the forward-looking regulation is to prevent a digital business with bottleneck power from
exercising it in order to protect entrants on the platform so that they have the chance to become
competitors of the platform.
Platform strategies to prevent multi-homing are an important category for the DA to include in
its analysis of foreclosure. A platform contract to induce single-homing on one side of a multi-
sided market can be used to reduce competition (e.g., a loyalty payment to drivers of a ride-
sharing service). Likewise, a platform can make it costlier for users to multi-home among
applications on the platform by, for example, limiting data sharing. Such strategies can foreclose
entrants and harm competition; appropriate regulation could limit their use by firms with
bottleneck power.
The second reason for forward-looking regulation is to prevent digital businesses with bottleneck
power from inefficiently expropriating rents created by complements on their platform. As
described above, this harm is less well-protected by antitrust laws so the need for enhanced
181
For a deeper discussion of the power of discrimination in preventing entry by disintermediation, see Section
II.2.B.3, supra.
94
regulation will be greater when considering foreclosure on the platform. The DA may be able to
build on the concept of “business to platform” regulation that is developing in Europe to create
effective non-discrimination rules.
182
The motivation of this EC regulatory effort is to create a
“fair, predictable, sustainable, and trusted legal environment” in which complementors and
content providers can invest safely and contribute to social welfare.
183
The Vestager Report
states that platforms “[i]f dominant . . . have a responsibility to ensure that they regulate in a pro-
competitive way. Dominant platforms should be subject to a duty to ensure interoperability with
suppliers of complementary services.”
184
Likewise, the Furman Report recommends developing
a platform code of conduct to ensure fairness.
185
The DA could promulgate regulations prohibiting the foreclosure of a competing content
provider on a platform that is vertically integrated. The authority would need to develop rules to
identify foreclosure that might depend on finding certain anticompetitive conduct, market share,
or market power to make such determinations. The DA must also account for potential pro-
competitive innovations that a company with bottleneck power seeks to provide. The data
collected by the DA will allow it to examine such outcomes and weigh all factors to make pro-
competitive determinations. This balancing will be costly and, despite its best efforts, the
regulator may err. However, as the report emphasizes, non-intervention is also costly. Non-
discrimination rules in the past suffered from slow and expensive adjudication, which limited
their usefulness.
186
Strategies for speedy adjudication are addressed in detail below.
c. Bundling
A digital platform with bottleneck power may have a contract with complementors (e.g., retailers
on an ecommerce platform) that bundles together access to their transaction data along with
logistics services. This could have harmful anticompetitive effects.
187
As described above, the
business may also compete against those retailers on its ecommerce site. The business could use
182
For regulatory developments, see Fairness in Platform-to-Business Relations, EURO. COMMN,
https://ec.europa.eu/info/law/better-regulation/initiatives/ares-2017-5222469_en.
183
Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on Promoting Fairness and
Transparency for Business Users of Online Intermediation Services, at 3, COM (2018) 238 final (Apr. 26, 2018),
https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=CELEX%3A52018PC0238 (“The present proposal aims at
ensuring a fair, predictable, sustainable and trusted legal environment for business users, corporate website users,
providers of online intermediation services and online search engines alike, which will limit the occurrence and the
impact of harmful platform-to-business trading practices occurring in certain online activities, thereby safeguarding
trust in the online platform economy and preventing further legal fragmentation of the Digital Single Market.”).
184
EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 71.
185
See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 5.
186
See Leased Commercial Access Modernization of Media Regulation Initiative, Further Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking, 33 FCC Rcd 5901 (2018), https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-18-80A1.pdf, at 1, n.2 and
accompanying text (noting that “the [Federal Communication] Commission’s 2008 Leased Access Order . . . has
[been] stayed for a decade in conjunction with several judicial appeals”).
187
Retailers may accept what otherwise seems like a bad bargain due to the importance of being available to
customers through the bottleneck. See Section II.2.B.4., supra for a discussion of bottleneck firms’ ability to dictate
business terms.
95
the retailers’ data to learn which products are selling well and expropriate the ideas and strategies
of the retailer. That data advantage over rivals can enable a company to achieve and/or maintain
critical economies of scale, better predict consumer behavior, and form a powerful barrier to
entry for potential competitors.
188
Bundling may also discourage multi-homing.
Another example of possibly harmful bundling could occur when a platform owner requires
installation of a bundle of applications. Those apps might be chosen to block the growth of rival
apps that were extracting rents from the platform or threatening to be a future competitor of the
platform. The Internet of Things will create more settings in which bundling policy will be
critical. Will a consumer’s new fridge arrive with a supply contract from Amazon’s
WholeFoods? Will the consumer be able to change that contract in some period of time, or is the
consumer permitted to purchase the fridge without any contract?
An antitrust case in these settings may be ineffective in protecting entrants and competition in
digital bottleneck businesses due to the complexity of the problem and the slow pace of
litigation. However, the DA could establish regulations that prohibit anticompetitive bundling by
firms with bottleneck power. Such a firm would be required to demonstrate that its bundle was
on balance procompetitive if foreclosure was alleged. The DA could require unbundling and an
offer to business customers of a choice of contracts in the case of anticompetitive bundling. The
DA would need to enforce such contracts.
iii. DA-Enforced Remedies for Antitrust Violations
When a company has been found liable for violating the antitrust laws, the antitrust authority is
tasked with devising a remedy to restore the lost competition. A fine does not restore lost
competition. No longer engaging in the illegal conduct may help the next entrant or complement
that wishes to interoperate, but it will typically not restore the competition that has already been
lost, particularly in the face of durable barriers to entry that protect incumbent digital platforms.
Antitrust authorities are good at enforcing structural remedies that require no ongoing
monitoring, such as requiring a divestiture between a platform and its content, or the sharing of a
dataset or intellectual property with the entrant, royalty-free. However, reducing entry barriers
often requires a remedy that involves ongoing monitoring, as do behavioral remedies, such as
firewalls between platforms and content. As mentioned above, the DA could also enforce
remedies for antitrust violations identified and addressed by existing antitrust agencies.
189
Below
are some types of remedies for which the DA would be a more appropriate body to enforce.
190
188
See Section I.1.B.1, and Section I.2.A.3, supra.
189
See Section III.3.A., supra.
190
For example, ongoing monitoring. See Section III.3.A, supra.
96
1) Data Sharing
Anticompetitive conduct may result in a market that has tipped in favor of a single provider
which then benefits from unparalleled access to data. In those cases, a new entrant may find it
impossible to service users with new products as it lacks the scale needed for effective operation.
Data sharing could restore the lost competition. The relevant data to share may not be just
historical data, but present and future data also. Because data are non-rivalrous, an incumbent
can both share its data with a competitor and also keep it. Thus, access to data forms a very
important remedy in the toolkit of both the antitrust authority and the DA. The Furman Report
recommends that agencies mandate “data openness” (which leads to data sharing) to enhance
competition.
191
The Vestager Report likewise recognized that data sharing can help level the
playing field.
192
2) Full Protocol Interoperability
Another useful tool that could restore lost competition is an open protocol and interoperability
standard that would be available for entrants to use on a continuing basis and allow them to
overcome network effects. A bottleneck business whose anticompetitive conduct created a
monopoly position could be required to interoperate with its competitors. Entrants, previously
rendered uncompetitive by network effects, could use the APIs to bring information from the
incumbent bottleneck firm to its own users. In a social media context this would allow the users
of the new service to see not only all the content on their own service, but also content from
friends on an incumbent site that was subject to an interoperability requirement. The network
barrier to entry would no longer protect the incumbent firm, which would then encourage entry
into the industry. Interoperability would facilitate ongoing competition on the merits of the user
experience, rather than on the size of the installed base, and potentially stimulate robust
competition.
Interoperability managed by the DA would be necessary due to the ongoing monitoring needed,
the likelihood of technical change, and the incentive for non-cooperation by the incumbent firm.
The DA could mandate the standard protocols or APIs to be applied and tightly control the
process to avoid having competition undermined by actions of the dominant firm. The DA would
need a process to update protocols at the time of the launch of new functionality or innovation. It
would need rules to protect the privacy and choice of users on one service as some form of
access to them is granted to users of another service. With easy interoperability, users will be
free to make a real choice about which service they prefer. This will encourage new market entry
and vigorous competition between providers.
191
See U.K. COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 10, 74, § 2.79.
192
See EC COMPETITION REPORT, supra note 1, at 98-107.
97
3) Non-discrimination
The clear and simple remedy for a case when a bottleneck digital business favors its own content
or complement is divestiture of one of the businesses, either the bottleneck business or the
content/applications. This removes both the incentive and the ability for the conduct. However,
this structural remedy could be costly to consumers in various ways, leading to the conclusion
that a behavioral non-discrimination remedy might be more appropriate. Requiring a dominant
bottleneck to abide by a non-discrimination rule could induce competitive entry by allowing
complementary businesses to thrive and eventually become horizontal competitors to the
bottleneck.
193
The ongoing monitoring necessary to enforce this type of remedy in a specific
antitrust case is not an ideal role for an antitrust agency. However, if the antitrust agency
determines that such a remedy run by the DA would restore and protect competition, the law
would allow it the option of requesting the DA to carry out the remedy. A speedy mechanism to
adjudicate complaints would be of key.
4) Un-Bundling
As described above, the requirement to unbundle contracts could be an antitrust remedy that is
less onerous than divestiture. Such a remedy would require ongoing monitoring that would best
be performed by the DA.
iv. Aligning other policies with competition
In addition to the structural competition tools, the authority should be empowered to align
privacy protection, as well as AI and algorithmic oversight, with competition goals. Privacy
protections that shield consumers from misuse or over-collection of their data can be set up in a
way that raises or lowers entry barriers. This point is often forgotten inside a specialist agency
and therefore we strongly suggest that the DA’s mandate include evaluating and then directing
regulatory solutions in a pro-competitive direction.
194
Mandating that the DA have vigorous
competition as one of its goals will help to make sure that potentially complex analysis takes
place and that the needs of entrants are taken seriously when making policy decisions. The
authority may also need to examine the development and use of algorithms to capture consumer
attention, maximize advertising revenue, and drive consumer purchases or information selection,
and examine how structural or other tools can promote competition in that space as well.
v. Adjudication Process
Adjudication of disputes by this new authority must be quick. Due to the fast pace of change in
these industries, the short amount of time it takes to destabilize or eliminate an entrant, the
193
See Section III.2.B.3.E.
194
It is worth considering whether the competition function and staff of the DA will be more effective when
incorporated into other agency tasks or separated into a distinct division.
98
substantial discrepancy in bargaining power between digital bottlenecks and their business
customers, and the necessity to use government resources efficiently, a speedy process is crucial.
This could be achieved through mandatory deadlines for dispute resolution or other procedural
rules requiring the authority to produce a decision in a fixed number of days, as well as by
crafting clear standards that are simple to enforce where possible.
The regulatory framework outlined above would coexist with and complement antitrust
enforcement, only blocking transactions and preventing behavior that harm the public interest in
ways clearly defined by Congress and that strengthen the reach of antitrust. The authority could
help elucidate the common line-drawing problem of what behaviors are in or out of the reach of
antitrust through communication with the antitrust enforcement agencies and with the public. An
effective regulator will devise rules that promote competition and new avenues for innovation.
V. Conclusion
This report has discussed the unique combination of attributes of large digital platforms and their
tendency toward entrenched market power. The entry barriers that result are in part due to certain
characteristics of digital technology, but in part also due to behaviors of market participants.
Consumers create entry barriers with their behavioral biases, and incumbents create entry
barriers through strategic use of contracts and technologies, as well as by engaging in various
other activities. The resulting monopoly or concentrated market structures do not serve
consumers as well as would a market in which entry is a credible, or actual, reality.
Public policy has been slow to respond to economic harms resulting from these conditions. Such
harms include advertising prices that are higher than would be expected in a more competitive
environment. The markups distort decision-making and are subsequently passed through to
consumers in the goods and services they buy. There are also quality harms. Platforms have
incentives to provide low quality in order to keep users “engaged” and sell more ads. More
generally, a lack of competition lessens the pressure on any platform to deliver high quality to its
customers for fear that they will move to a rival platform. Perhaps most importantly, insufficient
competition among and for digital platform position distorts and reduces innovation in a sector
that has been—and, under the right conditions, will continue to be—the source of huge benefits
for consumers and society.
It is unlikely that these problems will self-correct, meaning new and revised rules and incentives
will be needed to prevent market power from entrenching a few dominant tech firms as
economic and social gatekeepers. The United States is very far behind the frontier in antitrust
enforcement, both because courts have taken a conservative view of what constitutes
anticompetitive conduct and because agencies have not yet developed expertise in digital
competition cases. Considerable work can be done by academics to help provide new relevant
knowledge and tools to both agencies and courts. It also may be necessary for Congress to pass
new legislation that revises the antitrust laws, establishes a specialist Competition Court, or
99
both. The committee believes that vigorously enforcing the antitrust laws under these conditions
would be likely to increase entry in digital platform industries, competition, and consumer
welfare. Moreover, such enforcement would result in remedies to restore competition that has
already been lost as well as serve as a deterrent to future anticompetitive conduct. Finally,
because the problems we identify may require action beyond antitrust, we also propose the
establishment of a new digital regulatory agency, or Digital Authority.
Such an agency could increase social welfare by establishing baseline market rules and
conditions that both promote competition and limit the dimensions of competition to those that
benefit consumers, rather than exploit them. In addition, the agency could assist in carrying out
modern competition enforcement, using burdens of proof that reflect new understandings of
market behaviors.
Whether the platforms that are dominant today have achieved that position entirely on the merits
bears further examination. If illegalities are determined, appropriate remedies will be needed to
restore the lost competition. However strong antitrust remedies likely will require coupling with
market-opening regulations to overcome market power that prevented competitive market entry.
Going forward, two important goals for public policy are ensuring entry and competition for
platforms, as well as creating competition on platforms. Forward-looking laws and regulations
should be geared to lowering entry barriers as much as possible and vigorously guarding against
exclusion, lock-in, and foreclosure in the platform context. Without a swift policy pivot to apply
these combined tools, digital markets may tip toward levels of entrenched power that undermine
the benefits of innovative digital businesses for American consumers.